Chapter8.txt 299 KB

1234567891011121314151617181920212223242526272829303132333435363738394041424344454647484950515253545556575859606162636465666768697071727374757677787980818283848586878889909192939495969798991001011021031041051061071081091101111121131141151161171181191201211221231241251261271281291301311321331341351361371381391401411421431441451461471481491501511521531541551561571581591601611621631641651661671681691701711721731741751761771781791801811821831841851861871881891901911921931941951961971981992002012022032042052062072082092102112122132142152162172182192202212222232242252262272282292302312322332342352362372382392402412422432442452462472482492502512522532542552562572582592602612622632642652662672682692702712722732742752762772782792802812822832842852862872882892902912922932942952962972982993003013023033043053063073083093103113123133143153163173183193203213223233243253263273283293303313323333343353363373383393403413423433443453463473483493503513523533543553563573583593603613623633643653663673683693703713723733743753763773783793803813823833843853863873883893903913923933943953963973983994004014024034044054064074084094104114124134144154164174184194204214224234244254264274284294304314324334344354364374384394404414424434444454464474484494504514524534544554564574584594604614624634644654664674684694704714724734744754764774784794804814824834844854864874884894904914924934944954964974984995005015025035045055065075085095105115125135145155165175185195205215225235245255265275285295305315325335345355365375385395405415425435445455465475485495505515525535545555565575585595605615625635645655665675685695705715725735745755765775785795805815825835845855865875885895905915925935945955965975985996006016026036046056066076086096106116126136146156166176186196206216226236246256266276286296306316326336346356366376386396406416426436446456466476486496506516526536546556566576586596606616626636646656666676686696706716726736746756766776786796806816826836846856866876886896906916926936946956966976986997007017027037047057067077087097107117127137147157167177187197207217227237247257267277287297307317327337347357367377387397407417427437447457467477487497507517527537547557567577587597607617627637647657667677687697707717727737747757767777787797807817827837847857867877887897907917927937947957967977987998008018028038048058068078088098108118128138148158168178188198208218228238248258268278288298308318328338348358368378388398408418428438448458468478488498508518528538548558568578588598608618628638648658668678688698708718728738748758768778788798808818828838848858868878888898908918928938948958968978988999009019029039049059069079089099109119129139149159169179189199209219229239249259269279289299309319329339349359369379389399409419429439449459469479489499509519529539549559569579589599609619629639649659669679689699709719729739749759769779789799809819829839849859869879889899909919929939949959969979989991000100110021003100410051006100710081009101010111012101310141015101610171018101910201021102210231024102510261027102810291030103110321033103410351036103710381039104010411042104310441045104610471048104910501051105210531054105510561057105810591060106110621063106410651066106710681069107010711072107310741075107610771078107910801081108210831084108510861087108810891090109110921093109410951096109710981099110011011102110311041105110611071108110911101111111211131114111511161117111811191120112111221123112411251126112711281129113011311132113311341135113611371138113911401141114211431144114511461147114811491150115111521153115411551156115711581159116011611162116311641165116611671168116911701171117211731174117511761177117811791180118111821183118411851186118711881189119011911192119311941195119611971198119912001201120212031204120512061207120812091210121112121213121412151216121712181219122012211222122312241225122612271228122912301231123212331234123512361237123812391240124112421243124412451246124712481249125012511252125312541255125612571258125912601261126212631264126512661267126812691270127112721273127412751276127712781279128012811282128312841285128612871288128912901291129212931294129512961297129812991300130113021303130413051306130713081309131013111312131313141315131613171318131913201321132213231324132513261327132813291330133113321333133413351336133713381339134013411342134313441345134613471348134913501351135213531354135513561357135813591360136113621363136413651366136713681369137013711372137313741375137613771378137913801381138213831384138513861387138813891390139113921393139413951396139713981399140014011402140314041405140614071408140914101411141214131414141514161417141814191420142114221423142414251426142714281429143014311432143314341435143614371438143914401441144214431444144514461447144814491450145114521453145414551456145714581459146014611462146314641465146614671468146914701471147214731474147514761477147814791480148114821483148414851486148714881489149014911492149314941495149614971498149915001501150215031504150515061507150815091510151115121513151415151516151715181519152015211522152315241525152615271528152915301531153215331534153515361537153815391540154115421543154415451546154715481549155015511552155315541555155615571558155915601561156215631564156515661567156815691570157115721573157415751576157715781579158015811582158315841585158615871588158915901591159215931594159515961597159815991600160116021603160416051606160716081609161016111612161316141615161616171618161916201621162216231624162516261627162816291630163116321633163416351636163716381639164016411642164316441645164616471648164916501651165216531654165516561657165816591660166116621663166416651666166716681669167016711672167316741675167616771678167916801681168216831684168516861687168816891690169116921693169416951696169716981699170017011702170317041705170617071708170917101711171217131714171517161717171817191720172117221723172417251726172717281729173017311732173317341735173617371738173917401741174217431744174517461747174817491750175117521753175417551756175717581759176017611762176317641765176617671768176917701771177217731774177517761777177817791780178117821783178417851786178717881789179017911792179317941795179617971798179918001801180218031804180518061807180818091810181118121813181418151816181718181819182018211822182318241825182618271828182918301831183218331834183518361837183818391840184118421843184418451846184718481849185018511852185318541855185618571858185918601861186218631864186518661867186818691870187118721873187418751876187718781879188018811882188318841885188618871888188918901891189218931894189518961897189818991900190119021903190419051906190719081909191019111912191319141915191619171918191919201921192219231924192519261927192819291930193119321933193419351936193719381939194019411942194319441945194619471948194919501951195219531954195519561957195819591960196119621963196419651966196719681969197019711972197319741975197619771978197919801981198219831984198519861987198819891990199119921993199419951996199719981999200020012002200320042005200620072008200920102011201220132014201520162017201820192020202120222023202420252026202720282029203020312032203320342035203620372038203920402041204220432044204520462047204820492050205120522053205420552056205720582059206020612062206320642065206620672068206920702071207220732074207520762077207820792080208120822083208420852086208720882089209020912092209320942095209620972098209921002101210221032104210521062107210821092110211121122113211421152116211721182119212021212122212321242125212621272128212921302131213221332134213521362137213821392140214121422143214421452146214721482149215021512152215321542155215621572158215921602161216221632164216521662167216821692170217121722173217421752176217721782179218021812182218321842185218621872188218921902191219221932194219521962197219821992200220122022203220422052206220722082209221022112212221322142215221622172218221922202221222222232224222522262227222822292230223122322233223422352236223722382239224022412242224322442245224622472248224922502251225222532254225522562257225822592260226122622263226422652266226722682269227022712272227322742275227622772278227922802281228222832284228522862287228822892290229122922293229422952296229722982299230023012302230323042305230623072308230923102311231223132314231523162317231823192320232123222323232423252326232723282329233023312332233323342335233623372338233923402341234223432344234523462347234823492350235123522353235423552356235723582359236023612362236323642365236623672368236923702371237223732374237523762377237823792380238123822383238423852386238723882389239023912392239323942395239623972398239924002401240224032404240524062407240824092410241124122413241424152416241724182419242024212422242324242425242624272428242924302431243224332434243524362437243824392440244124422443244424452446244724482449245024512452245324542455245624572458245924602461246224632464246524662467246824692470247124722473247424752476247724782479248024812482248324842485248624872488248924902491249224932494249524962497249824992500250125022503250425052506250725082509251025112512251325142515251625172518251925202521252225232524252525262527252825292530253125322533253425352536253725382539254025412542254325442545254625472548254925502551255225532554255525562557255825592560256125622563256425652566256725682569257025712572257325742575257625772578257925802581258225832584258525862587258825892590259125922593259425952596259725982599260026012602260326042605260626072608260926102611261226132614261526162617261826192620262126222623262426252626262726282629263026312632263326342635263626372638263926402641264226432644264526462647264826492650265126522653265426552656265726582659266026612662266326642665266626672668266926702671267226732674267526762677267826792680268126822683268426852686268726882689269026912692269326942695269626972698269927002701270227032704270527062707270827092710271127122713271427152716271727182719272027212722272327242725272627272728272927302731273227332734273527362737273827392740274127422743274427452746274727482749275027512752275327542755275627572758275927602761276227632764276527662767276827692770277127722773277427752776277727782779278027812782278327842785278627872788278927902791279227932794279527962797279827992800280128022803280428052806280728082809281028112812281328142815281628172818281928202821282228232824282528262827282828292830283128322833283428352836283728382839284028412842284328442845284628472848284928502851285228532854285528562857285828592860286128622863286428652866286728682869287028712872287328742875287628772878287928802881288228832884288528862887288828892890289128922893289428952896289728982899290029012902290329042905290629072908290929102911291229132914291529162917291829192920292129222923292429252926292729282929293029312932293329342935293629372938293929402941294229432944294529462947294829492950295129522953295429552956295729582959296029612962296329642965296629672968296929702971297229732974297529762977297829792980298129822983298429852986298729882989299029912992299329942995299629972998299930003001300230033004300530063007300830093010301130123013301430153016301730183019302030213022302330243025302630273028302930303031303230333034303530363037303830393040304130423043304430453046304730483049305030513052305330543055305630573058305930603061306230633064306530663067306830693070307130723073307430753076307730783079308030813082308330843085308630873088308930903091309230933094309530963097309830993100310131023103310431053106310731083109311031113112311331143115311631173118311931203121312231233124312531263127312831293130313131323133313431353136313731383139314031413142314331443145314631473148314931503151315231533154315531563157315831593160316131623163316431653166316731683169317031713172317331743175317631773178317931803181318231833184318531863187318831893190319131923193319431953196319731983199320032013202320332043205320632073208320932103211321232133214321532163217321832193220322132223223322432253226322732283229323032313232323332343235323632373238323932403241324232433244324532463247324832493250325132523253325432553256325732583259326032613262326332643265326632673268326932703271327232733274327532763277327832793280328132823283328432853286328732883289329032913292329332943295329632973298329933003301330233033304330533063307330833093310331133123313331433153316331733183319332033213322332333243325332633273328332933303331333233333334333533363337333833393340334133423343334433453346334733483349335033513352335333543355335633573358335933603361336233633364336533663367336833693370337133723373337433753376337733783379338033813382338333843385338633873388338933903391339233933394339533963397339833993400340134023403340434053406340734083409341034113412341334143415341634173418341934203421342234233424342534263427342834293430343134323433343434353436343734383439344034413442344334443445344634473448344934503451345234533454345534563457345834593460346134623463346434653466346734683469347034713472347334743475347634773478347934803481348234833484348534863487348834893490349134923493349434953496349734983499350035013502350335043505350635073508350935103511351235133514351535163517351835193520352135223523352435253526352735283529353035313532353335343535353635373538353935403541354235433544354535463547354835493550355135523553355435553556355735583559356035613562356335643565356635673568356935703571357235733574357535763577357835793580358135823583358435853586358735883589359035913592359335943595359635973598359936003601360236033604360536063607360836093610361136123613361436153616361736183619362036213622362336243625362636273628362936303631363236333634363536363637363836393640364136423643364436453646364736483649365036513652365336543655365636573658365936603661366236633664366536663667366836693670367136723673367436753676367736783679368036813682368336843685368636873688368936903691369236933694369536963697369836993700370137023703370437053706370737083709371037113712371337143715371637173718371937203721372237233724372537263727372837293730373137323733373437353736373737383739374037413742374337443745374637473748374937503751375237533754375537563757375837593760376137623763376437653766376737683769377037713772377337743775377637773778377937803781378237833784378537863787378837893790379137923793379437953796379737983799380038013802380338043805380638073808380938103811381238133814381538163817381838193820382138223823382438253826382738283829383038313832383338343835383638373838383938403841384238433844384538463847384838493850385138523853385438553856385738583859386038613862386338643865386638673868386938703871387238733874387538763877387838793880388138823883388438853886388738883889389038913892389338943895389638973898389939003901390239033904390539063907390839093910391139123913391439153916391739183919392039213922392339243925392639273928392939303931393239333934393539363937393839393940394139423943394439453946394739483949395039513952395339543955395639573958395939603961396239633964396539663967396839693970397139723973397439753976397739783979398039813982398339843985398639873988398939903991399239933994399539963997399839994000400140024003400440054006400740084009401040114012401340144015401640174018401940204021402240234024402540264027402840294030403140324033403440354036403740384039404040414042404340444045404640474048404940504051405240534054405540564057405840594060406140624063406440654066406740684069407040714072407340744075407640774078407940804081408240834084408540864087408840894090409140924093409440954096409740984099410041014102410341044105410641074108410941104111411241134114411541164117411841194120412141224123412441254126412741284129413041314132413341344135413641374138413941404141414241434144414541464147414841494150415141524153415441554156415741584159416041614162416341644165416641674168416941704171417241734174417541764177417841794180418141824183418441854186418741884189419041914192419341944195419641974198419942004201420242034204420542064207420842094210421142124213421442154216421742184219422042214222422342244225422642274228422942304231423242334234423542364237423842394240424142424243424442454246424742484249425042514252425342544255425642574258425942604261426242634264426542664267426842694270427142724273427442754276427742784279428042814282428342844285428642874288428942904291429242934294429542964297429842994300430143024303430443054306430743084309431043114312431343144315431643174318431943204321432243234324432543264327432843294330433143324333433443354336433743384339434043414342434343444345434643474348434943504351435243534354435543564357435843594360436143624363436443654366436743684369437043714372437343744375437643774378437943804381438243834384438543864387438843894390439143924393439443954396439743984399440044014402440344044405440644074408440944104411441244134414441544164417441844194420442144224423442444254426442744284429443044314432443344344435443644374438443944404441444244434444444544464447444844494450445144524453445444554456445744584459446044614462446344644465446644674468446944704471447244734474447544764477447844794480448144824483448444854486448744884489449044914492449344944495449644974498449945004501450245034504450545064507450845094510451145124513451445154516451745184519452045214522452345244525452645274528452945304531453245334534453545364537453845394540454145424543454445454546
  1. Chapter Eight.
  2. Managerialism: Irrationality and Authoritarianism in the
  3. Large Organization
  4. A. The Corporate Form and Managerialism.
  5. We have already seen, in the section of Chapter Three on the corporate form, that
  6. apologists for the corporate legal form have been forced to abandon much of Mises'
  7. "entrepreneurial corporation" doctrine, and concede ground to the proponents of the
  8. managerial revolution like Berle and Means. Stephan Kinsella, for example, argued:
  9. It is bizarre that there is this notion that owners of property are automatically liable for
  10. crimes done with their property... Moreover, property just means the right to control. This
  11. right to control can be divided in varied and complex ways. If you think shareholders are
  12. "owners" of corporate property just like they own their homes or cars--well, just buy a share
  13. of Exxon stock and try to walk into the boardroom without permission. Clearly, the complex
  14. contractual arrangements divide control in various ways: the managers, etc., really have
  15. direct control; subject to oversight by the directors... etc. But even here--to get a loan, the
  16. company has to agree to various covenants w/ the bank, that condition its right to use
  17. property. Even though the law would not call the bank an "owner" praxeologically it of
  18. course has a partial right to control the property. If you have a contract allowing rentacops to
  19. patrol the building--hey, they are partial owners too. If you are leasing from a landlord--so do
  20. they. If you allow the plumber in to fix the building--he has temporary right of control too.
  21. So what?1
  22. And in an email to the Libertarian Alliance's Sean Gabb, he "raise[d] doubts about the
  23. effective control that shareholders have over their companies, and wonder[ed] if they
  24. should not rather be placed in the same category as employees or lenders or contractors."2
  25. He continued to develop the same argument, in his response at Mises Blog to Gabb's
  26. article on the subject:
  27. ....You conceive of a shareholder as the "natural" owner of the enterprise. I am skeptical
  28. of relying on the conceptual classifications imposed by positive law. To me a shareholder's
  29. nature or identity depends on what rights it has. What are the basic rights of a shareholder?
  30. What is he "buying" when he buys the "share"? Well, he has the right to vote--to elect
  31. directors, basically. He has the right to attend shareholder meetings. He has the right to a
  32. certain share of the net remaining assets of the company in the event it winds up or dissolves,
  33. after it pays off creditors etc. He has the right to receive a certain share of dividends paid if
  34. 1
  35. Comment under Kevin Carson, "Corporate Personhood," Mutualist Blog, April 24, 2006
  36. <http://mutualist.blogspot.com/2006/04/corporate-personhood.html>.
  37. 2
  38. Sean Gabb "Thoughts on Limited Liability" Free Life Commentary, Issue Number 152, 26th September
  39. 2006 <http://www.seangabb.co.uk/flcomm/flc152.htm>.
  40. the company decides to pay dividends--that is, he has a right to be treated on some kind of
  41. equal footing with other shareholders--he has no absolute right to get a dividend (even if the
  42. company has profits), but only a conditional, relative one. He has (usually) the right to sell
  43. his shares to someone else. Why assume this bundle of rights is tantamount to "natural
  44. ownership"--of what? Of the company's assets? But he has no right to (directly) control the
  45. assets. He has no right to use the corporate jet or even enter the company's facilities, without
  46. permission of the management. Surely the right to attend meetings is not all that relevant.
  47. Nor the right to receive part of the company's assets upon winding up or upon payment of
  48. dividends--this could be characterized as the right a type of lender or creditor has.3
  49. As I said in Chapter Three, this was a long step for Kinsella, considering that he
  50. initially argued (with Hessen) that the corporation was simply a contractual device for
  51. property owners to pool their property and appoint managers for it as they saw fit. In
  52. order to absolve shareholders of liability for the actions of their alleged "servants," he was
  53. eventually forced to concede most of the ground claimed by such theorists of the
  54. "managerial corporation" as Berle and Means.
  55. Along the same lines Alchian and Demsetz suggested (as mentioned in passing in
  56. Chapter Six) that the "ownership" role of the stockholder might be largely a myth, and
  57. that the only real difference between stockholders' ownership of equity and bondholders
  58. ownership of debt (or more specifically the difference between preferred stockholders,
  59. and common stockholders and bondholders) was one of degree.
  60. Instead of thinking of shareholders as joint owners, we can think of them as investors,
  61. like bondholders, except that the stockholders are more optimistic than bondholders about
  62. the enterprise prospects....
  63. If we treat bondholders, preferred and convertible preferred stockholders, and common
  64. stockholders and warrant holders as simply different classes of investors... why should
  65. stockholders be regarded as "owners" in any sense distinct from the other financial investors?
  66. The identification of stock ownership with voting rights over the corporation, in fact,
  67. was far less in earlier days:
  68. Investment old timers recall a significant incidence of nonvoting common stock, now
  69. prohibited in corporations whose stock is traded on listed exchanges.... The entrepreneur in
  70. those days could hold voting shares while investors held non-voting shares, which in every
  71. other respect were identical. Nonvoting shareholders were simply investors devoid of
  72. ownership connotations.4
  73. In our discussions of the corporation's internal calculation problem in Chapter Seven,
  74. we saw that assertions of "entrepreneurial" control of the corporation assume one of two
  75. 3
  76. Stephan Kinsella, "Sean Gabb's Thoughts on Limited Liability," Mises Economics Blog, September 26,
  77. 2006 <http://blog.mises.org/archives/005679.asp>.
  78. 4
  79. Armen A. Alchian and Harold Demsetz, "Production, Information Costs, and Economic Organization,"
  80. The American Economic Review, p. 789n.
  81. alternative mechanisms: Mises' entrepreneur with double-entry bookkeeping, or Mises'
  82. and Manne's market for control. The interesting part is that, in addition to Mises'
  83. "entrepreneurial firm" subject to direct capitalist control, both thinkers propose a
  84. mechanism for entrepreneurial "control" short of direct control of the corporation
  85. hierarchy itself. That mechanism is the ability of the investor to shift funds in his
  86. portfolio away from firms that do not perform to his satisfaction, and to firms that
  87. maximize profits or otherwise meet his criteria for performance, in search of the
  88. investment vehicles with the highest rates of return. This last method, a version of "dollar
  89. democracy," treats the corporation largely as an autonomous, self-owned entity, with the
  90. capitalist rentier classes in the position of customers whose main instrument of control is
  91. the ability to take their business elsewhere. As we will see below, all these mechanisms
  92. are considerably less effective than their proponents believe: the "entrepreneurial"
  93. investor's direct control over the board of directors and senior management is largely a
  94. legal fiction; the threat of hostile takeover, although real at times, tends to arise at widely
  95. separated intervals and to be subject to mitigating responses by management; the threat of
  96. capital flight is limited by the corporation's reliance on retained earnings for the majority
  97. of finance and by minimal reliance on new share issues.
  98. The arguments of Kinsella, and of Alchian and Demsetz, taken together, suggest that
  99. capitalist ownership of the individual corporation is a myth, in the sense that a particular
  100. corporation is the property of its stockholders (or preferred stockholders with voting
  101. rights) in any real sense.
  102. Instead, the corporation is an agglomeration of unowned capital, under the control of
  103. a self-perpetuating managerial oligarchy. As Luigi Zingales quotes John Kay: "...if we
  104. asked a visitor from another planet to guess who were the owners of a firm... by
  105. observing behaviour rather than by reading text books in law or economics, there can be
  106. little doubt that he would point to the company's senior managers."5
  107. This is borne out by Martin Hellwig's analysis, which shows that Manne's "market for
  108. corporate control" is more myth than reality. Hellwig argues that the concept of residual
  109. claimancy can be properly applied not so much to the shareholders as to management,
  110. which has the power "to disfranchise outside shareholders..., [and] that in all
  111. circumstances not otherwise provided for, ... has the effective power to set the rules of
  112. decision making so as to immunize itself against unwanted interference from outsiders."6
  113. The theory that management is controlled by outside capital markets assumes a high
  114. degree of dependence on outside finance. But in fact management's first line of defense is
  115. to mimimize its reliance on outside finance. Management tends to finance new
  116. 5
  117. John Kay, The Business of Economics (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1996), p. 111, in Luigi
  118. Zingales, "In Search of New Foundations," The Journal of Finance, vol. lv, no. 4 (August 2000), p. 1638.
  119. 6
  120. Martin Hellwig, "On the Economics and Politics of Corporate Finance and Corporate Control," in Xavier
  121. Vives, ed., Corporate Governance: Theoretical and Empirical Perspectives (Cambridge: Cambridge
  122. University Press, 2000), p. 98.
  123. investments as much as possible with retained earnings, followed by debt, with new
  124. issues of shares only as a last resort.7 Issues of stock are important sources of investment
  125. capital only for startups and small firms undertaking major expansions.8 Most
  126. corporations finance a majority of their new investment from retained earnings, and tend
  127. to limit investment to the highest priorities when retained earnings are scarce.9 As Doug
  128. Henwood says, in the long run "almost all corporate capital expenditures are internally
  129. financed, through profits and depreciation allowances." Between 1952 and 1995, almost
  130. 90% of investment was funded from retained earnings, while new stock issues amounted
  131. to 4% of total investment.10
  132. The threat of shareholder intervention is diluted, likewise, by stock buy-backs.
  133. According to Henwood, U.S. nonfinancial corporations from 1981-96 retired some $700
  134. billion more stock than they issued.11
  135. Hellwig makes one especially intriguing observation, in particular, about financing
  136. from retained earnings. He denies that reliance primarily on retained earnings necessarily
  137. leads to a "rationing" of investment, in the sense of underinvestment; internal financing,
  138. he says, can just as easily result in overinvestment, if the amount of retained earnings
  139. exceeds the value of available opportunities for rational capital investment.12 This seems
  140. to bear out Schumpeter's argument, cited in Chapter Three, that double taxation of
  141. corporate profits promoted excessive size and centralization, by encouraging
  142. reinvestment in preference to the issue of dividends. Of course it may result in structural
  143. misallocations and irrationality, to the extent that retention of earnings prevents dividends
  144. from returning to the household sector to be invested in other firms, so that
  145. overaccumulation in the sectors with excessive retained earnings comes at the expense of
  146. a capital shortage in other sectors.13 Henwood contrasts the glut of retained earnings,
  147. under the control of corporate bureaucracies with a shortage of investment opportunities,
  148. to the constraints the capital markets place on small, innovative firms that need capital the
  149. most.14
  150. The high debt to equity ratio might seem to cast some doubt on the primacy of
  151. internal financing. For example "newson," a commenter at Mises Blog, challenged my
  152. claims on the insignificance of outside finance:
  153. i find this hard to square with the fact that the debt-to-equity ratio on the sp500 averaged
  154. at about one over 2007. the tax deductibility of interest makes debt financing particularly
  155. 7
  156. Ibid., pp. 100-101.
  157. Ralph Estes, Tyranny of the Bottom Line: Why Corporations Make Good People Do Bad Things (San
  158. Francisco: Berrett-Koehler Publishers, 1996), p. 51.
  159. 9
  160. Hellwig, pp. 101-102, 113.
  161. 10
  162. Doug Henwood, Wall Street: How it Works and for Whom (London and New York: Verso, 1997), p. 3.
  163. 11
  164. Ibid., pp. 3, 72-73.
  165. 12
  166. Hellwig, pp. 114-115.
  167. 13
  168. Ibid., p. 117.
  169. 14
  170. Henwood, Wall Street, pp. 154-155.
  171. 8
  172. attractive vis-a-vis equity. look at the numbers on equity buy-backs in the past years.
  173. management certainly have had an interest in raising share prices, and maintaining eps in
  174. order to maximize their option-rich remuneration packages.15
  175. But the primacy of internal finance refers to internal capital investments in new
  176. production capabilities, whereas--as Henwood shows--the overwhelming bulk of
  177. corporate borrowing goes to finance takeovers or stock buybacks, not new investment.
  178. The mergers and acquisitions of the 80s and 90s were the source of $1.9 trillion in debt.16
  179. In short, the corporate economy finances new investment almost entirely
  180. independently of the capital markets.
  181. Hellwig's thesis that management is the real "residual claimant" is reinforced by
  182. management's role in making the very rules by which the corporation is governed,
  183. including the rules by which shareholders exercise whatever power they have.
  184. Management insiders, as the primary influence on the internal bylaws of the corporation,
  185. have considerable power to dilute the power of shareholders.17
  186. Likewise, the board of directors, which theoretically represents shareholders and
  187. oversees management in their interests, is in fact likely composed mostly of inside
  188. directors who take their positions at the invitation of management and are controlled by
  189. management's proxy votes. As a result, they are likely to engage in a mutual logrolling
  190. process in which management support the directors' continued tenure, the directors
  191. rubber-stamp large salary increases for the CEO, and the internal oligarchy perpetuates
  192. itself through cooptation rather than outside election.18 Proxy contests are almost always
  193. lost by dissident stockholders, because management rigs the rules against them.19
  194. Of course this still leaves the threat of hostile takeover, of which "entrepreneurial"
  195. theories of the corporation make so much. But it is overrated for the same reason as other
  196. alleged instruments of "entrepreneurial" control: management controls the rules. Hostile
  197. takeovers tend to occur in waves every few decades, and to run their course in a few years
  198. as management devises new strategies for deflecting the threat. That is very much the
  199. case with the much-ballyhooed wave of hostile takeovers of the '80s, which supposedly
  200. rendered the managerial corporation obsolete. In fact, as Hellwig argued, the rise in
  201. hostile takeovers in the '80s was the immediate result of some very specific innovations,
  202. like junk bond financing, and quickly ran its course as management developed new
  203. techniques like the "poison pill" and "shark repellent" to limit the threat of hostile
  204. takeover--i.e., they took advantage of their control, as incumbents, over the internal
  205. 15
  206. Newson comment under Ben O'Neill, "How to Bureaucratize the Corporate World," Mises Economics
  207. Blog, January 23, 2008 <http://blog.mises.org/archives/007691.asp>.
  208. 16
  209. Henwood, pp. 73-76.
  210. 17
  211. Hellwig, pp. 109, 112.
  212. 18
  213. Myles L. Mace, Directors: Myth and Reality. Revised ed. (Boston: Harvard Business School Press,
  214. 1986), in Estes, op. cit., pp. 64-67.
  215. 19
  216. Ibid., p. 69.
  217. governance rules of the corporation. There were a significant number of takeovers and
  218. mergers in the '90s, but they were for the most part friendly takeovers: strategic attempts
  219. to increase market shares and take advantage of alleged synergies, rather than hostile
  220. takeovers motivated by governance issues.20 And in friendly takeovers, of course, the
  221. management of the acquired firm is much more likely to be in collusion than in
  222. opposition.
  223. M. J. Roe argued, in Strong Managers, Weak Owners, that American law artificially
  224. increased the autonomy of management by weakening the direct influence of the financial
  225. sector and preventing the kind of direct industrial ownership by banks that is prevalent in
  226. Europe.21 Hellwig questions this argument, showing that the financial sector is more
  227. accurately seen as part of the network of corporate insiders, and is more likely to side
  228. with management in protecting its autonomy from outside challenges.22
  229. In addition, in the case of mergers and acquisitions, the "market for corporate control"
  230. argument used by Mises and Manne makes an unwarranted assumption: that the
  231. acquisition is motivated by the interest of the acquiring firm's stockholders, and not that
  232. of its senior management. In fact Ben Branch argued, not long after Manne wrote on the
  233. market for corporate control, that most mergers did not "work to the advantage of the
  234. acquiring fund's stockholders":
  235. Thus, either corporate officials are consistently misjudging merger opportunities, or a great
  236. deal of merger activity is motivated by managerial interests.23
  237. Doug Henwood backs this up. Surveying the literature on post-merger corporate
  238. performance, in mergers and acquisitions from the turn of the 20th century through the
  239. '80s, he found that both acquiring and acquired firms tended to do worse, in terms of
  240. profits and stock performance, after a merger. The active parties in hostile takeovers
  241. were not, as Mises and Manne would have us think, "entrepreneurial" stockholders. They
  242. were empire-building managers.
  243. Managers feel richer and more powerful if their firm is growing, and if the business can't
  244. grow quickly on its own, then they can gobble up others. Related to this is the idea that
  245. while mergers may not result in a higher rater of return (profits divided by invested capital),
  246. they may result in a higher quantity of profits, that is more zeroes on the bottom line.24
  247. The threats of hostile takeover and capital flight are also limited, in practical terms, by
  248. the cognitive problems we considered in Chapter Seven: the inability of investors to
  249. 20
  250. Hellwig, op. cit., p.111.
  251. M. J. Roe, Strong Managers, Weak Owners: The Political Roots of American Corporate Finance
  252. (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1994).
  253. 22
  254. Hellwig, op. cit., pp. 126-127.
  255. 23
  256. Ben Branch, "Corporate Objectives and Market Performance," Financial Management vol. 2 no. 2
  257. (Summer 1973), p. 26.
  258. 24
  259. Henwood, Wall Street, pp. 278-281.
  260. 21
  261. accurately assess the meaning of market data on share value and returns. Even when the
  262. threat of hostile takeover is real, it is limited by the ability of outsiders to assess the
  263. meaning of performance data. Their basis for comparison is conditioned by the existence
  264. of a "normal" rate of profit for each industry, which in turn reflects the average level of
  265. managerialism. So given restraints on competition, and given the small number of
  266. oligopoly firms sharing a common institutional culture, the "good" profit-maximizing
  267. corporations that avoid takeover are pretty atrocious in terms of any absolute standard of
  268. efficiency. And the capitalist voting blocks, even when able to exercise relatively strong
  269. control over management, have been conditioned by the social and ideological hegemony
  270. of managerialism, and all its assumptions, in regard to what is "normal" management
  271. behavior and the normal corporate way of doing things. As Ben Branch argues,
  272. By not doing as well as they might, managers widen the gap between actual and potential
  273. market value. This encourages takeover bids and proxy fights....
  274. [But s]ince it is often quite difficult for outsiders to evaluate management, there may be
  275. considerable sacrifice of shareholders' interests before management's position is threatened.25
  276. For that matter, as we also saw in Chapter Seven, to the extent that pressure to
  277. maximize profits is effective, it is precisely the effectiveness of such pressure that may
  278. result in destructive behaviors that cripple long-term productivity.
  279. Another possible instrument of shareholder control sometimes put forward is the
  280. concerted influence of institutional investors. But institutional stock ownership is often
  281. nearly as dispersed as ownership by individual shareholders. Henry Hansmann gives the
  282. example of General Motors, whose top five institutional shareholders together own only
  283. six percent of stock.26
  284. Rakesh Khurana, one of the ablest historians of corporate managerialism, nevertheless
  285. buys largely into the conventional view that changes in corporate governance and
  286. managerial incentives amounted to a revival of the entrepreneurial corporation, and the
  287. reassertion of shareholder control at the expense of management. He portrays the
  288. changes in executive incentives (executive stock options and performance-based pay) and
  289. the alleged resurgence of the "market for corporate control" (the hostile takeover wave of
  290. the '80s) as part of a fundamental power shift from managerial to investor capitalism.27
  291. In this, I believe he is fundamentally mistaken. With the exception of a relatively
  292. brief period of hostile takeovers, which (as Hellwig explains) was soon thwarted by
  293. management counter-measures, there was no real loss of managerial autonomy or shift of
  294. power.
  295. 25
  296. Branch, "Corporate Objectives aand Market Performance," p.. 24.
  297. Henry Hansman, The Ownership of Enterprise (Cambridge and London: The Belknap Press of Harvard
  298. University Press, 1996), p. 57.
  299. 27
  300. Khurana, pp. 302, 318.
  301. 26
  302. Managerial behavior did indeed change in response to the change in incentives; but it
  303. was a voluntary change in behavior by autonomous management, acting to maximize its
  304. own self-interest in an environment of altered incentive structures. The discretion was
  305. still management's. And it is questionable, at the very least, whether these changed
  306. incentives elicited behavior in the real interest of shareholders. As already described in
  307. Chapter Seven, such "performance-based" incentives have, in fact, encouraged
  308. management to maximize apparent short-term profit at the expense of long-term
  309. profitability, in order to inflate their own short-term stock options and leave a gutted shell
  310. to the "owners."
  311. It's hard to deny, though, that the change in incentives led to a change in managerial
  312. culture. In place of the old organization man, the responsible and disinterested
  313. Weberian/Taylorist technocrat, arose the new entrepreneurial model of senior
  314. management, with superstar-CEOs like Jack Welch celebrated in the media. In the old
  315. days, CEOs tended to see themselves as being at the apex of the technostructure, rather
  316. than as entrepreneurs gaming the market to maximize their own compensation. After
  317. Iacocca, the focus of business culture shifted, in quite distasteful ways, to a cult of
  318. "leadership" and "vision,"28 reflected both in the business press, and in the proliferation of
  319. wretched (see "Ken Blanchard") management theory and motivational books in the
  320. 1990s. But this new kind of cowboy CEO, arguably, was in his own way even more of a
  321. maximizer of self-interest at the expense of shareholder value than his managerialist
  322. predecessor (see, for example, the discussion of Nardelli in Chapter Seven). Arianna
  323. Huffington, in Pigs at the Trough, provides many examples of corporate CEOs collecting
  324. enormous compensation packages for running their companies into the ground.29
  325. Khurana himself, interestingly, undercuts his own picture to a considerable extent by
  326. adding this qualification:
  327. For a while, investors and academics alike believed that pay-for-performance schemes
  328. such as stock option grants, an active market for corporate control, and the fiscal discipline
  329. of leverage would succeed in focusing managers on creating value for shareholders.
  330. Unforeseen by the intellectual architects of the revolution in economics and finance was that
  331. by deligitimating the old managerialist order and turning executives, in theory and practice,
  332. into free agents who owed their primary loyalty to a group who assumed no reciprocal
  333. obligations to them, they had cut managers loose from any moorings not just to the
  334. organizations they led or the communities in which those organizaitons were embedded but
  335. even, in the end, to shareholders themselves. The resulting corporate oligarchy had no roledefined obligation other than to self-interest. The unintended consequences of this
  336. revolution, first evident in the anomalies of executive pay in relation to individual and
  337. corporate performance first noticed in the late 1990s, have since the beginning of the current
  338. decade come to include the long string of corporate scandals involving misstated earnings,
  339. 28
  340. Ibid., pp. 355-362.
  341. Arianna Huffington, Pigs at the Trough: How Corporate Greed and Political Corruption are
  342. Undermining America (New York: Crown Publishers, 2003), pp. 43-55.
  343. 29
  344. backdated stock options, and various exotic variations on such themes that have as their
  345. common thread the enrichment of individual executives at the expense of shareholders,
  346. employees, and the public trust in the essential integrity of the system on which democratic
  347. capitalism itself depends.30
  348. That doesn't even take into account the problems with short-term stock value itself as
  349. a gauge of long-term profitability. Even when no fraud exists on the pattern of Enron or
  350. Tyco, the very incentive to maximize short-term share price (and with it one's stock
  351. options) only for the period until one moves on to another management job, creates a
  352. rational incentive for the kinds of milking and asset-stripping described here and in
  353. Chapter Seven.
  354. In light of all these considerations, the arguments of C. Wright Mills and Martin Sklar
  355. on the "corporate reorganization of the capitalist class" and the "corporate transformation
  356. of capitalism"--that the interlocked corporate economy, rather than being directly
  357. "owned" by capitalist shareholders, is largely an instrument of indirect, collective control
  358. by the capitalist class, whose power is conditioned by the managers it has incorporated as
  359. junior partners)--make much more sense.31 The capitalist hegemony over the economy is
  360. conditioned by the managerial instrument through which it must work.
  361. So the corporate economy as a whole is capitalist. But the real, direct capitalist
  362. ownership is over investment funds only, and is exercised over the corporate organization
  363. only through the power to withdraw money from one investment and move it to another
  364. with higher yields. And that power itself, remember, is limited by management's
  365. tendency to rely whenever possible on retained earnings in preference to outside finance.
  366. The managerialist corporation is profit-maximizing in some regards, but not in others.
  367. As seen in Chapter Seven, it indeed promotes short-term profit at the expense of longterm productivity, because of the perverse incentives to even the most destructive forms
  368. of profit maximization presented by the capital markets (including management stock
  369. options). As I argued in Chapter Three, the corporate form provides a convenient form of
  370. plausible deniability, by which investors are able to use the threat of withdrawal of funds
  371. to pressure corporate management to maximize profits "by any means necessary," while
  372. being able to maintain a plausible pose of ignorance and irresponsibility regarding the
  373. means actually taken by corporate management. And corporate management is able to
  374. hide behind the corporate veil in order to avoid personal responsibility for any harmful
  375. actions the corporation takes to maximize profits. That veil becomes a travesty,
  376. especially, when management is able to pump up its own stock options by ethically and
  377. 30
  378. Rakesh Khurana, From Higher Aims to Hired Hands: The Social Transformation of American Business
  379. Schools and the Unfulfilled Promise of Management as a Profession (Princeton and Oxford: Princeton
  380. University Press, 2007), p. 364.
  381. 31
  382. C. Wright Mills, The Power Elite. Revised edition (Oxford University Press, 1956, 2000); Martin Sklar,
  383. The Corporate Reconstruction of American Capitalism, 1890-1916: The Market, the Law, and Politics
  384. (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1988).
  385. legally shady actions taken under cover of the corporate form.
  386. Outside pressures to maximize profits are quite effective in matters of costexternalization. The most decent corporate manager, as an individual, will engage in the
  387. most anti-social acts as a manager, in the name of "shareholder value."
  388. Profit maximization is far less operative, however, when it comes to the interests of
  389. management itself. The threat of capital flight is an effective disciplinary tool in cases of
  390. profit lowering policies like "corporate social responsibility" and the like, precisely
  391. because such policies are not a part of the normal corporate culture. There is, therefore,
  392. the potential for real competition between corporations based on whether they do or do
  393. not follow such practices. As a result, "socially responsible" corporations are largely
  394. limited to a niche market appealing to the psychic returns of Bobos and limousine
  395. liberals. Outside of this niche market, "social responsibility" consists largely of
  396. greenwashed rhetoric that involves little if any cost to the bottom line.
  397. On the other hand, there is much less chance of competition between corporations
  398. based on the degree of internal management self-dealing, because the overwhelming
  399. majority of corporations operate with a shared managerialist culture that takes selfdealing for granted as a normal part of business. At the same time, the prevalence in most
  400. industries of oligopoly firms that derive large rents from consumers means that the
  401. inefficiency costs of managerialism cause little competitive harm; as a result,
  402. shareholders can afford to pay the high rents going to management.
  403. As a result, the capitalists' control over outside investment funds, and their threat of
  404. capital flight, is only able to spur profit maximization in areas that do not directly affect
  405. the managerialists' class interests. The collective interests of the managers as a class are
  406. the limit to capitalists' control over the corporate economy.
  407. To put it another way, there is a wide range of conceivable systems that are
  408. compatible with high returns on capital; the present system, out of all those possibilities,
  409. involves a tradeoff of less than an optimal return on capital in return for optimizing the
  410. interests of the managerial class. What we have is the highest rate of return on capital
  411. that's possible given the managerialist organization of production.
  412. In many cases, the interests of stockholders would be better served if management
  413. ranks were drastically cut, resources were shifted into more production workers and
  414. higher wages, and workers had more control over the production process. But that would
  415. be a death blow to the managerial culture in the average large American corporation.
  416. Management has a great deal of autonomy in promoting its own interests within the
  417. corporation, along with the power to thwart outside interference. Any reform that
  418. management perceives as contrary to its self-interest will be killed. What's more, part of
  419. it is not so much mendacity as genuine cluelessness: they can't think of any way to
  420. improve how workers are doing things except to increase the number of managers
  421. swarming around and poking into everything they do.
  422. Several years ago, Scott Adams wrote an appendix to The Dilbert Principle on his
  423. "OA5" management philosophy. That philosophy entailed, mainly, ruthlessly weeding out
  424. those not directly involved in producing or improving the product. As I understand it, that
  425. means in practice that the average American corporation would 1) streamline its hierarchy
  426. until it had managerial staff in the same proportions as its European and Japanese
  427. counterparts; 2) put the savings into increased production staff and increased pay; and 3)
  428. replace all the "quality" and "process improvement" committees with a great deal more
  429. direct worker control over how the production process is organized on the shop floor.
  430. The result would likely be skyrocketing productivity and morale.
  431. None of this is to deny--far from it--the extent to which rentier incomes on land and
  432. capital reflect special privilege, or the fact that labor is exploited by the propertied classes
  433. under the present system. Certainly in the past few decades, the income of the very top
  434. plutocracy has exploded upward. But on the whole, I suspect that the average worker
  435. suffers as much from managerialism and the resources eaten up by bureaucratic overhead
  436. as from the income of rentiers. That is suggested by the statistics below on the
  437. compensation of supervisory employees now compared to thirty years ago--an increase
  438. whose value rivals the average rate of profit.
  439. The rentier classes, to a large extent, are held hostage by their dependence on the
  440. managerial stratum. The monopoly profits of big business depend on cartelization by the
  441. state; and given this situation, even at bare minimum a considerable power is entailed for
  442. the managerial bureaucracy. The large corporate size promoted by state intervention
  443. increases the leverage of managers against shareholders. According to Khurana,
  444. "Really big" organizations required large numbers of managers, which i turn created more
  445. leverage for management vis-a-vis owners. The political and legal decisions that removed
  446. constraints on corporate growth thus aided managers in their struggle with owners for control
  447. of the corporation.32
  448. The agency problems of absentee ownership and wage labor, with their attendant
  449. requirements for internal hierarchy and authoritarianism, also promote managerialism.
  450. Rationalistic legitimizing rhetoric of managerial authority, based on the "systems
  451. paradigm," scientific management, and production control, were most prevalent in
  452. periods of labor strife.33 Empowerment of labor over the production process, despite its
  453. almost certain benefits to productivity in the short run, would greatly increase the
  454. bargaining power of labor in the long run, and likely imperil profits as much as
  455. management salaries.
  456. The owners are also held hostage, somewhat counterintuitively, by the way the
  457. corporate form treats capital as the ostensible source of control rights. Management's
  458. 32
  459. 33
  460. Khurana, From Higher Aims to Hired Hands, pp. 29-30.
  461. Ibid., p. 31.
  462. freedom to promote its interests at the expense of workers leads, simultaneously, to the
  463. promotion of management interests at the expense of productivity, which reduces the
  464. overall returns. To a large extent the shareholders and workers have a common interest,
  465. versus management, in dividing the additional productivity gains that might result from
  466. the elimination of management self-dealing. A comment by John Micklethwait is
  467. interesting, in this light. After a survey of arguments for stakeholder capitalism, and his
  468. own dismissive comments about its performance in countries like Germany where it's
  469. been tried, he argued that stakeholder interests would be best served by strengthening
  470. shareholder interests at the expense of management:
  471. This defense of shareholding may sound horribly complacent. What about all those fat
  472. cats paying themselves gigantic salaries? And what about the golden parachutes that allow
  473. these weighty felines to get rich on failure? In fact, the best way to deal with the anxieties
  474. that have given rise to the recent stakeholder debate is to give more power to shareholders,
  475. not less. Study almost any corporate disaster... and you find a board acting without anybody
  476. looking over its shoulder.34
  477. Micklethwait got it completely backward. He might have forgotten that the gigantic
  478. salaries and golden parachutes came about in the '80s, in the cowboy management culture
  479. that resulted from attempts to strengthen shareholder control. As those attempts (stock
  480. options, bonuses, hostile takeovers, etc.) have demonstrated, genuine shareholder control
  481. over management is as much a pipe dream as genuine citizen control over a continentsized "representative democracy." Owing to Michels' Iron Law, corporate management
  482. can never be subject to effective control by those on the outside. But it could be
  483. effectively checked by others on the inside. Ironically, it's the myth of management
  484. responsibility to shareholders, as a legitimating ideology of managerial control, that
  485. insulates management from control by internal stakeholders. As a result, we get the
  486. problem we see described by Luigi Zingales in Chapter Nine: the portion of firm value
  487. created by its human capital is expropriated by management, and internal stakeholders
  488. exist in a zero-sum relationship with management in which it is in their interest to
  489. minimize personal investment of effort and skill in the firm. The firm runs far below
  490. optimal efficiency, because the system of ownership denies its main source of valueadded a proportional share in the value they create.
  491. To summarize the lessons of this section: Michels' Iron Law of Oligarchy applies
  492. very much to the corporation: regardless of the ostensible aims of an organization and the
  493. formal accountability of its leadership to some constituency, in fact it ossifies over time
  494. into a power structure whose primary purpose is to serve those directing the organization.
  495. Thus, from a means, organization becomes an end. To the institutions and qualities
  496. which at the outset were destined simply to ensure the good working of the party machine...,
  497. a greater importance comes ultimately to be attached than to the productivity of the
  498. 34
  499. John Micklethwait and Adrian Wooldridge, The Witch Doctors: Making Sense of the Management
  500. Gurus (New York: Times Books, 1996), p. 184.
  501. machine.35
  502. ....By a universally applicable social law, every organ of the collectivity, brought into
  503. existence through the need for the division of labor, creates for itself, as soon as it becomes
  504. consolidated, interests peculiar to itself. The existence of these special interests involves a
  505. necessary conflict with the interests of the collectivity. Nay, more, social strata fulfilling
  506. peculiar functions tend to become isolated, to produce organs fitted for the defense of their
  507. own peculiar interests. In the long run they tend to undergo transformation into distinct
  508. classes.36
  509. ...."It is organization which gives birth to the dominion of the elected over the electors, of
  510. the mandatories over the mandators, of the delegates over the delegatorsw. Who says
  511. organization, says oligarchy."37
  512. Oliver Williamson, in Markets and Hierarchies, elaborated on the relevance of
  513. Michels' principle to the corporation:
  514. ....[The] special significance [of Michels' remarks] for present purposes is that
  515. bureaucratic insularity varies directly with organizational size.... Given finite spans of
  516. control, increasing firm size leads to taller hierarchies in which leaders are less subject to
  517. control by lower-level participants. The resulting bureaucratic insularity of the leadership
  518. permits it, if it is so inclined, to both entrench and engross itself.
  519. As compared, however, with a voluntary organization, the matter of legitimacy in the
  520. business firm is less in relation to lower-level participants than it is to the stockholders. The
  521. control problems in each case nevertheless turn on identical consideration, namely, the
  522. information-impactedness issue. Since problems of stockholder control in this sense
  523. typically become more severe as the firm grows in size and complexity..., larger size is
  524. associated with greater opportunities for discretion. Where the leadership exercises these
  525. opportunities by permitting slack and indulging in personal consumption, size limitations
  526. follow--especially if lower-level performance varies directly with higher-level example,
  527. which normally is to be expected.38
  528. In a footnote, Williamson adds that the issue of the firm leadership's insularity from
  529. lower-level participants is "also relevant," particularly in regard to "the status pathology
  530. of large organizations" and distorting rewards in favor of those at the top, at the expense
  531. of those at the bottom.39
  532. Robert Shea, in his aptly titled article "Empire of the Rising Scum," argued that any
  533. organization--regardless of its ostensible external mission--would eventually be
  534. 35
  535. Robert Michels, Political Parties: A Sociological Study of the Oligarchical Tendencies of Modern
  536. Democracy. Translated by Eden and Cedar Paul (New York: The Free Press, 1962), p. 338.
  537. 36
  538. Ibid., p. 353.
  539. 37
  540. Ibid., p. 365.
  541. 38
  542. Oliver Williamson, Markets and Hierarchies, Analysis and Antitrust Implications: A Study in the
  543. Economics of Internal Organization (New York: Free Press, 1975), pp. 127-128.
  544. 39
  545. Ibid., p. 127n.
  546. dominated by those whose primary skill was the acquisition and maintenance of power.
  547. That the more authoritarian organizations survive and prevail goes generally unnoticed
  548. because people focus on the objectives of organizations, which are many and varied, rather
  549. than on their structures, which lend to be similar...
  550. But the more an organization succeeds and prospers, the more it is likely to be diverted
  551. from its original ideals, principles and purposes...
  552. Why does this happen? Because the better an organization is at fulfilling its purpose, the
  553. more it attracts people who see the organization as an opportunity to advance themselves.
  554. The ability to get ahead in an organization is simply another talent, like the ability to play
  555. chess, paint pictures, do coronary bypass operations or pick pockets. There are some people
  556. who are extraordinarily good at manipulating organizations to serve their own ends. The
  557. Russians, who have suffered under such people for centuries, have a name for them-apparatchiks. It was an observer of apparatchiks who coined the maxim, "The scum rises to
  558. the top."
  559. The apparatchik's aim in life is to out-ass-kiss, out-maneuver, out-threaten, out-lie and
  560. ultimately out-fight his or her way to the top of the pyramid-any pyramid....
  561. Unfortunately, the existence of this talent means that every successful organization will
  562. sooner or later be taken over by apparatchiks. As such people achieve influence within the
  563. organization, whenever there is a conflict between their own interest and the interest of the
  564. organization, their interests will win out. Thus, over time, the influence of apparatchiks will
  565. deflect the organization further and further from its original intent....
  566. Whatever the original aim of the organization, to publish books, to heal the sick, to share
  567. information about computers, once it has been taken over by apparatchiks, it will acquire a
  568. new aim--to get bigger. It doesn't matter whether a bigger organization will fulfill its purpose
  569. as well, serve its customers or constituents as well, or be as good a place for people to work.
  570. It will get bigger simply because those at the top want it to get bigger. Apparatchiks do to
  571. organizations what cancer viruses do to cells; they promote purposeless growth....40
  572. B. Self-Serving Policies for "Cost-Cutting," "Quality" and "Efficiency"
  573. We already saw, in Chapter Six, Jensen's and Meckling's argument that management
  574. has an incentive to shift capital investment from allocations that maximize productivity,
  575. to allocations that feather their own nests.41 If management are relatively free to choose
  576. their level of perquisites, subject only to their diluted loss of returns from ownership of a
  577. 40
  578. Robert Shea, "Empire of the Rising Scum" (1990). The article originally appeared in the now-defunct
  579. Loompanics catalog, and is now preserved on Carol Moore's website
  580. <http://www.carolmoore.net/articles/empirerisingscum.html>.
  581. 41
  582. Jensen and Meckling, "Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs and Ownership
  583. Structure," op. cit.
  584. small fraction of corporate stock, "[their] welfare will be maximized by increasing [their]
  585. consumption of non-pecuniary benefits."42 Oliver Williamson, in The Economics of
  586. Discretionary Behavior (originally his PhD dissertation), anticipated their argument and
  587. elaborated on it at great length.43 One term he coined, "expense preference," is especially
  588. useful:
  589. ...[M]anagers do not have a neutral attitude toward all classes of expenses. Instead, some
  590. types of expenses have positive values attached to them: they are incurred not merely for
  591. their contributions to productivity (if any) but, in addition, for the manner in which they
  592. enhance the individual and collective objectives of managers.44
  593. Further, as we already saw in Chapter Seven, the market's perverse incentives to
  594. maximize short-term profit by gutting long-term productivity will mean that even the
  595. profit-maximization incentive presented by management's stock options will more likely
  596. than not cause them to game the system to maximize their options at the expense of the
  597. organization's long-term welfare.
  598. Although Meckling and Jensen expect shareholders to pay monitoring costs to the
  599. point at which they cease to pay off in increased productivity, the added agency costs of
  600. separating ownership from control will still "not... result in the firm being run in a manner
  601. so as to maximize its value."45
  602. As one might guess, given all these considerations, any time it is left to management
  603. to find new ways of improving "quality," their solution is likely to be everything but
  604. increasing the resources and autonomy of production workers; again, as you might
  605. expect, it will rather involve expanding the power of management with even more
  606. committees, meetings, tracking forms, etc., so that production workers have even more
  607. interference and paperwork to deal with, and less time to get their real work done.
  608. This is true even when management pays lip service to a management theory fad that
  609. calls for empowering workers, and eliminating process inefficiencies resulting from
  610. bureaucratic interference. The problem is that any such theory is implemented by bosses
  611. --which means that any theory, no matter how empowering its rhetoric, will translate in
  612. practice into rewarmed Taylorism.46 If corporate management adopted Jeffersonianism as
  613. a management philosophy, it would ignore the part about inalienable human rights and
  614. local self-government, and just keep the part about screwing your slaves.
  615. 42
  616. Ibid., p. 18.
  617. Oliver Williamson. The Economics of Discretionary Behavior: Managerial Objectives in a Theory of
  618. the Firm (Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall, Inc., 1964).
  619. 44
  620. Ibid., p. 33.
  621. 45
  622. Jensen and Meckling, p. 30.
  623. 46
  624. I should mention that this and all other references to Taylorism, unless otherwise specified, are to the
  625. conventional understanding of Taylorism. The actual approach of Taylor himself, arguably, was
  626. considerably more nuanced and less authoritarian. I am indebted to Eric Husman of Grim Reader blog for
  627. pointing this out to me. [cite article]
  628. 43
  629. Such management initiatives have one thing in common: they all fail.
  630. "Empowerment" fads, which depend more than anything on employee support and
  631. enthusiasm, are killed for want of support and enthusiasm when employees inevitably
  632. perceive the self-serving reality behind the official happy talk.
  633. All too frequently, years of work and millions of dollars in salaries and consulting fees
  634. are wiped out by a single thoughtless bureaucratic memo or insensitive authoritarian
  635. comment, an unanticipated top-down change in organizational policy, resistance to change
  636. brought about by managerial miscommunication or misunderstanding, or lack of genuine
  637. employee enthusiasm for implementing the change.
  638. What is missed in these efforts is that the system of management, regardless of the skills
  639. and dedication of individual managers, reduces morale, and prevents employees from
  640. dedicating their efforts to improving quality, productivity, and customer service.47
  641. Although most managers are probably not as frank (even with themselves) as this
  642. senior executive of a London tech company, quoted by Jeffrey Nielsen, his comment is a
  643. pretty good statement of management's real, operational attitude toward "empowerment"
  644. lurking behind all the official happy talk:
  645. I was trying to help them organize a decision-making process that would gather input from
  646. all the employees, when I encountered stiff resistance from the senior executive. He bluntly
  647. informed me that employees should have no influence on the direction or decisions of the
  648. company. They were, he told me, as if imparting some esoteric management knowledge,
  649. "meant to be used like light bulbs: you screw 'em in, you turn 'em on, you burn 'em out.
  650. Then you replace 'em."48
  651. By the way, here's a neat little example of empowerment: Chloe at Corporate Whore
  652. blog received an email from the VP for Human Resources, proposing a bulletin board of
  653. "wanted" and "for sale" items. The idea was to reduce the large volume of emails,
  654. addressed to "All," listing such items. The problem?
  655. The bulletin board would be glass-covered--behind lock and key. Never mind the fact that we
  656. already have a bulletin board in the kitchen with NO glass covering it, which is already
  657. being used for that purpose.
  658. How would it work?... They plan to have the ‘associate’ submit the ad for approval to
  659. HR, which will then post the ad on the board for 10 business days. On the 7th day, the
  660. ‘associate’ will receive a notice that their ad is about to ‘expire’ and that if they wish to
  661. ‘renew’ it, they need to notify HR.49
  662. 47
  663. Kenneth Cloke and Joan Goldsmith, The End of Management and the Rise of Organizational Democracy
  664. (San Francisco: John Wiley and Sons, Inc., 2002), p. 45.
  665. 48
  666. Jeffrey Nielsen, The Myth of Leadership: Creating Leaderless Organizations (Palo Alto, Calif.: DaviesBlack Publishing, 2004), p. 9.
  667. 49
  668. Chloe, "Important People," Corporate Whore, September 21, 2007
  669. That still sounds like it leaves entirely too much discretion to the workers. Perhaps it
  670. would be safer to require two people to turn their keys at the same time, like in a missile
  671. silo. Any time you find yourself wondering why the "wikified enterprise" or "Enterprise
  672. 2.0" has such a hard time catching on with management, just go back and read about that
  673. bulletin board.
  674. We have also seen, in Chapter Seven, that each level of a hierarchy creates slack.
  675. Whenever possible managers, like all bureaucrats, like to increase the size of their
  676. domain and the number of staff under their control. The number of "direct reports" is a
  677. mark of prestige. They will increase the size of their domain even when it interferes with
  678. the efficient running of their existing domain. A good example of this is the behavior of
  679. Pentagon apparatchiks who divert funds to new weapons programs, at the expense of
  680. providing adequate pay, training, fuel, ammunition, and maintenance for existing
  681. personnel and equipment. Considering a couple of news items in the '90s--the Strategic
  682. Rocket Forces having their electrical power cut off for non-payment, and the main
  683. munitions storage facility for the Murmansk fleet blowing itself into the stratosphere for
  684. want of proper storage or maintenance--it appears these tendencies are cross-national.
  685. Anthony Downs describes the phenomenon, as it appears in the public sector
  686. bureaucracy:
  687. An official can more easily add to his power by obtaining more subordinates than by
  688. increasing his degree of control over his existing subordinates.
  689. ...Officials tend to react to change by attempting to increase their overall appropriations
  690. rather than by reallocating their existing appropriations.50
  691. But when absolute cuts in a firm, division or department are necessary, managers will
  692. direct them primarily to production workers, while preserving as much as possible of the
  693. staff attached to their offices. Management's approach to "increasing productivity" and
  694. "cutting costs" will mean decimating productive resources while leaving their own petty
  695. empires intact. As the downsizing of production workers and increased workloads lead to
  696. the proliferation of errors, management will respond by devoting still more resources to
  697. what Deming called "exhortations," "slogans," and "revival meetings," and Drucker
  698. called "management by drives." Any "reform" carried out by management will serve
  699. mainly to increase the power of managers.
  700. Cost-cutting in corporate bureaucracies closely resembles its counterpart in
  701. government bureaucracies. Lacking any explicit budget line-item for "waste, fraud, and
  702. abuse," senior management simply sets arbitrary figures to cut, say 20 or 30%, and leaves
  703. <http://www.corporatewhore.us/important-people/>.
  704. 50
  705. Anthony Downs, Inside Bureaucracy. A RAND Corporation Research Study (Boston: Little, Brown and
  706. Company, 1967), p. 267.
  707. the details to subordinates in the bureaucracy. In private industry, this takes the form of
  708. cutting out entire categories of production workers and consolidating their job
  709. descriptions, or reducing entire categories of workers by some arbitrary percentage. Of
  710. course, the last thing to be cut is management--and management itself is cut only from the
  711. bottom up. Their petty bureaucratic empires, the real purpose of the organization from
  712. the perspective of those actually running it, remain intact.
  713. Robert Jackall, in Moral Mazes, recounts just such a process after the new CEO of
  714. "Covenant" corporation took over. He ordered the presidents of its subsidiaries to carry
  715. out thorough reorganizations with "census reduction," but left the details entirely up to
  716. them (aside from setting aside some top management posts for his cronies). In the
  717. "Alchemy" subsidiary, the new president ("Smith") carried out a series of firings Jackall
  718. refers to as "the purge," and promoted his personal clients from his former division of the
  719. company to leadership positions.
  720. Smith met the Covenant CEO's financial targets in 1980, but the company entered a
  721. period of falling profits during the 1981 recession. Alchemy met only 60% of the profit
  722. target, and even then only with considerable accounting sleight-of-hand. In the ensuing
  723. period, the atmosphere of fear and paranoia resembled that of the Stalinist purge era, with
  724. rumors of Smith's disfavor flying wildly and everyone attempting to divert any potential
  725. disfavor from himself by betraying his colleagues. Senior management people positioned
  726. themselves for advancement in the event of Smith's fall, and betrayed him and each other.
  727. One senior management figure, notorious as an amoral "troubleshooter," publicly accused
  728. everyone who missed a staff meeting held during a record blizzard of disloyalty to the
  729. company.
  730. As the recession worsened in 1982, the Covenant CEO pressured Smith to
  731. "aggressively cut staff" and "streamline operations" in order to "emerge lean and poised"
  732. for the recovery. Later that year, the CEO demanded a 30% reduction in staff at
  733. Alchemy. Smith fired 200 people, mostly technical support people rather than
  734. management. Alchemy's earnings continued to fall, however, and pressure from the CEO
  735. increased.
  736. By this point, the watchword in the corporation had become "manage for cash," and the CEO
  737. wanted some businesses sold, others cut back, still others milked, and costs slashed.
  738. Particular attention began to be focused on the chemical company's environmental protection
  739. staff....
  740. In the fall of 1982, Smith resigned as president of Alchemy. The Byzantine rumor
  741. mill reached a new high among the courtiers in senior management, speculating on the
  742. identity of Smith's successor and the patronage networks that might result. Again, the
  743. waves of backstabbing and betrayal began in anticipation of an organizational shakeup.
  744. The CEO's choice for a new president, "Brown," was a former division head earlier
  745. demoted by Smith to make way for his own cronies. Brown was identified as "the CEO's
  746. boy," who owed everything to him, and had a mandate to pursue further staff cuts
  747. ruthlessly in order to cut costs to the CEO's satisfaction. The scrambling for position and
  748. the betrayals kicked up yet another notch. Brown fired another 150, this time however
  749. mainly from management. The surviving managers saw this as a violation of the
  750. unwritten management code, and management became increasingly hostile.
  751. In the meantime, the CEO began an aggressive campaign of acquisitions--mostly
  752. mature companies, which belied his claim to be focusing on tech startups with high
  753. growth potential.51
  754. This concurrent gutting of productive assets (especially staff), and irrational capital
  755. investments, is a common pattern in the corporate world.
  756. For reasons we examined in Chapter Seven, what large capital expenditures are made
  757. are typically made in an environment of calculational chaos, with little idea of their
  758. opportunity cost and no realistic estimate as to their likely effect on the organization's
  759. productivity.
  760. When management decimates productive resources, at the same time it chooses some
  761. productive resources to leave largely untouched; and as we saw in Chapter Seven, the
  762. choice of what to cut and what to leave intact reflects no discernable criterion of
  763. efficiency. In fact the calculation problems in the corporation make any such efficiency
  764. judgments largely arbitrary, so that management has little idea of the opportunity costs of
  765. the capital investments it does make.
  766. Bob Lewis uses the analogy of a hot-air balloon.52 When the balloon's losing altitude,
  767. the pilot can either jettison ballast or heat up the air inside. The problem is that
  768. management is so out of touch with the production process that it can't tell the air heating
  769. device from the ballast. And since that heater is pretty damn heavy, jettisoning it ought to
  770. give the balloon a nice boost (at least for a few quarters, until the air cools off).
  771. In this analogy, of course, the air heater refers to the productive resources that
  772. generate revenue. Daniel Gross puts it into concrete corporate terms:
  773. This type of self-defeating cost-cutting often occurs at knowledge businesses whose only
  774. real asset is smart, motivated employees....
  775. To be sure, if companies were indifferent to costs across the board, they wouldn't be in
  776. business. But the penny-pinching is aimed squarely at the vast productive middle. Top
  777. executives are generally unaffected.53
  778. 51
  779. Robert Jackall, Moral Mazes: The World of Corporate Managers (New York: Oxford University Press,
  780. 1988), pp. 25-32.
  781. 52
  782. Bob Lewis, "Don't cut off your own head: Corporate cost-cutting as a goal is always a mistake,"
  783. InfoWorld, September 11, 2000
  784. <http://www.infoworld.com/articles/op/xml/00/09/11/000911oplewis.html>.
  785. 53
  786. "Pinching the Penny-Pinchers: idiotic examples of corporate cost-cutting," Slate, September 25, 2006
  787. After all, an MBA is someone who would break up every stick of furniture in his
  788. house and throw it in the furnace, and then brag about how good the numbers look this
  789. month without the fuel oil bill. Now, a production worker could tell you that anyone who
  790. rewrites mission statements or core values, or has anything to do with Fish! Philosophy,
  791. is almost certainly ballast, in Lewis's analogy. The problem is that the real ballast in a
  792. company is in a position to give itself a huge bonus for throwing the air heater overboard.
  793. The company is run by ballast, which creates something of a conflict of interest when it
  794. comes to "maximizing productivity."
  795. One of my favorite writers on corporate culture, Jerome Alexander, puts it in
  796. appropriately jaundiced terms:
  797. I will predict that these same “leaders” will eventually move on to enjoy hefty salaries and
  798. lofty positions with different firms. They are heroes you know. They’ll commiserate with
  799. other executives at their new establishments and share stories about how the employees at
  800. their old companies let them down, couldn’t see the big picture, couldn’t execute their
  801. brilliant strategies, etc. They’ll probably even play off their newly acquired “expertise” at
  802. closing down operations, disposing of assets, etc. Then they’ll be allowed to work their
  803. magic all over again.
  804. I wonder when the garage sale will occur? Maybe they’ll sell the forklifts and office
  805. equipment to help fund their exit packages. It’s a shame but predictable because they have no
  806. shame.54
  807. And when management makes large capital investments, they are apt to resemble
  808. Hayek's predictions for a planned economy: uneven development, with productive
  809. resources underfunded or gutted in some sectors and overbuilt in others, and no clear idea
  810. of the comparative cost or likely productive returns of spending anywhere.
  811. A survey by McKinsey Quarterly found that, on average, corporate-level executives
  812. considered many of their firms' capital investment decisions to be bad ideas in retrospect:
  813. corporate-level executives responding to the survey with an opinion indicate that 17 percent
  814. of the capital invested by their companies went toward underperforming investments that
  815. should be terminated and that 16 percent of their investments were a mistake to have
  816. financed in the first place. Business unit heads and frontline managers say 21 percent of
  817. investments should not have been approved and indicate another 21 percent should be
  818. terminated.
  819. In addition to worrying about underperforming investments, a sizable number of survey
  820. <http://www.slate.com/id/2150340/>.
  821. 54
  822. Jerome Alexander, "Honey, We've Shrunk the Company!" The Corporate Cynic, July 20, 2007
  823. <http://thecorporatecynic.wordpress.com/2007/07/20/honey-we%e2%80%99ve-shrunk-the-company/>.
  824. respondents also indicate that a significant number of investments should have been made
  825. but were not. Corporate-level executives who have an opinion say it was a mistake not to
  826. provide funding for 21 percent of all rejected investments even though the forecast rate of
  827. return for the projects met or exceeded their companies’ benchmarks. Business unit heads
  828. and frontline managers say nearly twice as many should have received funding.
  829. It’s worth noting that these figures exclude a significant number of survey respondents:
  830. roughly 40 percent, for example, don’t have a point of view on how many investments should
  831. be terminated. This figure could be a warning sign that postmortem analysis is infrequent at
  832. many companies. A consistent finding is that nearly 40 percent of frontline managers don’t
  833. know their companies’ typical rate of return on investments over the past few years.
  834. Corporate-level executives generally have a much better sense of the returns the
  835. company earned on its investments. Yet the level of awareness among senior executives
  836. doesn’t necessarily translate into effective input: when asked what best explains the approval
  837. of the company’s least successful project in recent memory, 45 percent of executives at all
  838. levels say it was approved because “a senior leader advocated the project."55
  839. This strongly suggests that capital investment decisions are made in a prevailing
  840. atmosphere of groupthink and bureaucratic toadyism in which critical analysis is
  841. unwelcome.
  842. ...the less-than-ideal combination of optimism, risk aversion, and one-off decision making is
  843. perhaps exacerbated by the prominence of corporate politics. Respondents say that behindthe-scenes lobbying and logrolling—and sometimes outright deception—are fairly frequent
  844. and seem to inhibit constructive debate and dissent throughout the resource allocation
  845. process.
  846. Corporate politics interferes not only with the free expression of opinion on the
  847. wisdom of courses of action being considered, but with the availability of information
  848. needed for assessment:
  849. In many organizations, corporate politics appear to play a significant role in resource
  850. allocation decisions, adding an additional layer of complexity to the other problems that
  851. interfere with a company’s initial sound financial approach to decision making.
  852. For example, more than 60 percent of respondents say business unit and divisional heads
  853. form alliances with peers or lobby someone more senior in the organization at least
  854. “somewhat” frequently.... Interestingly, frontline managers report more lobbying—some 70
  855. percent say it occurs more than “somewhat” frequently—than do corporate-level executives
  856. (51 percent). Also, respondents at public companies report a greater incidence of lobbying
  857. than do those at private ones.
  858. Beyond simple politicking, 36 percent of respondents say managers hide, restrict, or
  859. 55
  860. "How Companies Spend Their Money: A McKinsey Global Survey," McKinsey Quarterly, June 2007
  861. <http://www.mckinseyquarterly.com/article_page.aspx?ar=2019&L2=21>.
  862. misrepresent information at least “somewhat” frequently when submitting capital-investment
  863. proposals. (On this measure there is almost no difference in the views of respondents from
  864. public and private companies.)
  865. As executives maneuver for position behind the scenes and sometimes even deceive one
  866. another, constructive debate and dissent appear to suffer. Only about a third of respondents,
  867. for instance, say executives frequently disagree about the attractiveness of future growth
  868. opportunities—hardly a topic that would seem to lend itself to unanimity. What’s more, a
  869. majority of respondents say it’s at least “somewhat” important to avoid contradicting
  870. superiors. The closer to the front line the respondent, the more important he or she rates the
  871. avoidance of such conflict.
  872. Corporate capital investments are also apt to be made in "an environment in which
  873. it’s common for estimates of project duration and sales to be excessively optimistic..."
  874. Another indication of executive optimism comes from the responses of a subset of
  875. executives who were asked to estimate a single project’s rate of return compared with other
  876. similar projects approved in the past. Roughly half say the new investment would have a
  877. return greater than 25 percent—a figure hard to reach in competitive market economies. Such
  878. findings are consistent with a strong tendency toward managerial optimism highlighted in
  879. other research.
  880. Management is especially prone, as Oliver Williamson writes, to persistent refusal to
  881. abandon sunk costs. He quotes Drucker's quip that "[n]o institution likes to abandon
  882. anything," and elaborates that "budget based institutions are more prone to persist with
  883. unproductive or obsolete projects than are revenue based institutions...."56
  884. Most downsizing is counterproductive in terms of its stated rationale. According to
  885. Richard Sennett, downsizings typically lower the productivity of the organization and
  886. result in lower profits. Early '90s studies by the American Management Association and
  887. the Wyatt Companies found that repeated downsizings resulted in "lower profits and
  888. declining worker productivity..." Less than half of the companies carrying out
  889. downsizings actually achieved their expense reduction goals, less than a third increased
  890. profitability, and less than a fourth increased productivity. Worker morale and
  891. motivation fell sharply after downsizing.57
  892. One reason, in addition to the degrading of productivity through understaffing and
  893. poor morale, is that savings from staffing cuts often go to subsidize increased
  894. management self-dealing and featherbedding, rather than to improve the bottom line. For
  895. example, Jackall refers to Covenant's expenditure of $100,000 on paint alone to repaint
  896. a plant whenever the CEO visited, and spending $10,000 to produce a single copy of a
  897. 56
  898. Oliver Williamson, Markets and Hierarchies, Analysis and Antitrust Implications: A Study in the
  899. Economics of Internal Organization (New York: Free Press, 1975), p. 122.
  900. 57
  901. Richard Sennett, The Corrosion of Character: The Personal Consequences of Work in the New
  902. Capitalism, p. 50.
  903. lavishly illustrated book on the plant's history and operations as a gift to the visiting
  904. CEO.58 Another example:
  905. ...just after the CEO of Covenant Corporation announced one of his many purges, legitimated
  906. by "a comprehensive assessment of the hard choices facing us" by a major consulting firm,
  907. he purchased a new Sabre jet for executives and a new 31-foot company limousine for his
  908. own use.... He then flew the entire board of directors to Europe on a Concorde for a regular
  909. meeting to review, it was said, his most recent cost-cutting strategies.59
  910. I'm reminded of an old news parody from National Lampoon: the federal government
  911. spent $5 billion to print two copies of a consumer pamphlet entitled "How to Save
  912. Money," and then burned them both.
  913. Another reason is that downsizing undoes the long-term and painstaking process of
  914. building human capital. It amounts to hollowing out a company, the moral equivalent of
  915. burning every stick of furniture in your house to save on this month's heating bill.
  916. Impressive short-term results can frequently be produced by hard-hitting managers who are
  917. generating a long-term catastrophe. Such conduct, says [Rensis] Likert, is encouraged by
  918. company reward systems that "enable a manager who is a 'pressure artist' to achieve high
  919. earnings over a few years, while destroying the loyalties, favorable attitudes, cooperative
  920. motivations, etc., among the supervisory and non-supervisory members of the organization."
  921. Such steamroller managers are frequently even promoted in recognition of their talents after,
  922. say, two or three years, which is just about the period that elapses before the damage begins
  923. to show up in the figures, leaving someone else to clean up (and no doubt take the blame for)
  924. the wreckage....
  925. What is happening, in effect, is that valuable resources are being disposed of and
  926. earnings given a short-term, artificial boost. No management would stand for such cavalier
  927. treatment of physical assets, and even if management were willing, the auditors would not
  928. be. Since human resources do not appear on the balance sheet, they can be liquidated at will
  929. by managers oriented to "the bottom line" (where net profit appears), in order to give a
  930. spurious injection to earnings.60
  931. A good example comes from Jerome Alexander of Corporate Cynic blog, an MBA
  932. and accountant who's spent his entire career in one middle management hell after another:
  933. Ann was an AP clerk whose position was eliminated last month due to co-sourcing. Prior
  934. to making the decision to let her go, no one bothered to ask Ann what she actually did or how
  935. she did it. It wouldn’t have mattered anyway because the new brainiacs at corporate HQ
  936. mandated that her position be eliminated on a date certain. Ann is gone.
  937. 58
  938. Jackall, Moral Mazes, pp. 22-23.
  939. Ibid. p. 144.
  940. 60
  941. David Jenkins, Job Power: Blue and White Collar Democracy (Garden City, New York: Doubleday &
  942. Company, Inc., 1973), p. 237.
  943. 59
  944. Poor Marie! Her misfortune was geography. She just happened to occupy the cubicle that
  945. was next to Ann’s. Marie is a staff accountant who has been with company for two years.
  946. Her only interface with Ann was the fact that they sometimes ate lunch together. Now Marie
  947. is being inundated with piles of mail, requests for emergency checks and investigations into
  948. why suppliers are not being paid. The operating and purchasing folks could care less about
  949. the co-sourcing project. They need things done.... Although Marie protests and tells them
  950. that she has nothing to do with accounts payable, they pester her incessantly anyway. Some
  951. will even wait for her to vacate her cubicle and then secretly swoop in to drop requests on
  952. her desk or chair. Marie’s voicemail and E-mail inbox are now full to overflowing. Marie is
  953. overwhelmed.
  954. Marie’s boss, Jim, is in the same boat. He’s only been with company for six months. Jim
  955. was initially told about the co-sourcing project and the fact that Ann would be leaving.
  956. Coming to work for a large corporation, Jim assumed that that the project had been well
  957. thought out. Get real Jim! Jim is now being attacked by even higher level operating and
  958. purchasing folks over the same issues. In Jim’s case, however, the frenzy goes beyond simply
  959. dealing with the needs of that constituency. It seems that Ann performed a lot of other
  960. accounting related tasks that were not exactly of an accounts payable nature. Ann had been
  961. with the company for over ten years and had survived a variety of previous reorganizations
  962. and downsizings (sorry “rightsizings”). Over the years and through necessity, Ann had taken
  963. on a variety of different tasks, all of which were mundane but no less essential. No disrespect
  964. to Ann, but in a lot of cases, she was really unaware of how important some of these duties
  965. were. She just performed them with aplomb. Now Jim is finding out exactly how deep in the
  966. hole he is.
  967. Jim has complained to the co-sourcing project leader at corporate HQ. He was informed
  968. that only certain accounts payable functions were being co-sourced and that many related
  969. duties were still his responsibility. But never fear, the bulk of the tasks had been transferred
  970. and he was only being left with a few. Uh Huh! He was also reminded of the cost savings
  971. associated with the project. In other words, “Too Bad.” Jim has also gone to his superiors to
  972. make them aware of the other problems. Tough luck, Jim! YOU should have thought of that
  973. earlier! Now Jim and Marie are stuck “holding the bag”. They are frantic, frazzled, and
  974. overwhelmed. Marie is actively seeking employment elsewhere.
  975. If my hunch is correct, you can multiply this story a hundred fold throughout the many
  976. divisions of the corporation....
  977. Instead of analyzing the workload first to eliminate the arbitrary, superfluous and
  978. redundant tasks and requirements, the focus is always on cutting the resources [emphasis
  979. added--from his mouth to God's ear!]. What a back-asswards approach to problem solving!
  980. Even after reducing staff, they will continuously come up with new requirements and even
  981. more compressed timetables - turning the arbitrary, the goofy, and superfluous into the
  982. essential.61
  983. 61
  984. Jerome Alexander, "'Outing' Some of the Downsides of Outsourcing," The Corporate Cynic, April 3,
  985. 2008 <http://thecorporatecynic.wordpress.com/2008/04/03/%e2%80%9couting%e2%80%9d-some-of-thedownsides-of-outsourcing/>.
  986. Or again:
  987. Last week, I watched as the company that I used to work for chopped another 35
  988. administrative and technical positions. The “non-surprise” for the survivors was that none of
  989. the work was eliminated and none of the deadlines were changed. Those who remain will
  990. just have to do more. But the few keep getting fewer, more tired, cranky and scared to death
  991. of what could be next. What a great way to work and live! To top it all off, the corporation
  992. has embarked upon one of those “Help us define the ‘values’ of our company” programs.
  993. Talk about adding insult to injury!62
  994. Or again:
  995. When the consultant asks, “Tell me what you do?” The accounts receivable clerk answers, “I
  996. post cash receipts to open invoices.” The consultant then responds with the infamous set up
  997. question,“ And how long does that take you every day?” “Oh, I can get that done in an hour
  998. or so,” beams the clerk trying to impress the consultant with their prowess and efficiency. I
  999. cringe every time I hear this because I can see the wheels turning behind the consultant’s
  1000. beady little eyes. “Hmmm, an hour a day! What are they doing for the other seven...? ....The
  1001. report back to the executive suite will be devastating. It will reinforce the notion that the
  1002. function is easy and equally unimportant....
  1003. What’s never asked about is the time and effort spent on supplier account maintenance
  1004. and customer account housekeeping, collection calls, straightening out paychecks or payroll
  1005. tax issues, inventory cycle counting and correcting bills of material issues. These are the
  1006. items that take the time and require the experience of the employees. This is the tender
  1007. loving care that will be lost when the positions are cut or consolidated. The effects won’t
  1008. surface immediately, but when they do--look out below. 63
  1009. What Alexander describes, the job-specific experience of employees, is human
  1010. capital. Management has little idea just how much the profitability of their organization
  1011. depends on such human capital, or how much of the organization's value comes from it.
  1012. To MBAs, schooled in the orthodoxy of Sloanism, human capital is not a productive
  1013. asset, but a cost. It follows naturally from such cluelessness, Harold Oaklander (a
  1014. specialist on workforce reductions at Pace University) argues that "many 'cost-cutting'
  1015. layoffs are actually counterproductive," because they interfere with "the firm's knowledge
  1016. system."64
  1017. Alex Markels and Matt Murray, at The Wall Street Journal (in an article appropriately
  1018. 62
  1019. Alexander, "Distressed about Job Stress? Don't Worry, Your Employer Isn't!" The Corporate Cynic,
  1020. March 25, 2008 <http://thecorporatecynic.wordpress.com/2008/03/25/distressed-about-job-stressdon%e2%80%99t-worry-your-employer-isn%e2%80%99t/>.
  1021. 63
  1022. Alexander, "What would “The Duke” say about the Trivialization of Non-executive Functions?" The
  1023. Corporate Cynic, April 10, 2008 <http://thecorporatecynic.wordpress.com/2008/04/10/what-would%e2%80%9cthe-duke%e2%80%9d-say-about-the-trivialization-of-non-executive-functions/>.
  1024. 64
  1025. Alvin Toffler, Powershift: Knowledge, Wealth and Power at the Edge of the 21st Century (New York:
  1026. Bantam, 1991), p. 222.
  1027. titled "Call it Dumbsizing"), describe the long-term effects of ill-advised and
  1028. indiscriminate downsizings, as practiced by most corporations:
  1029. Eastman Kodak Co. expected to save thousands of dollars a year when it laid off
  1030. Maryellen Ford in March in a companywide downsizing. But within weeks, Kodak was
  1031. paying more for the same work.
  1032. Ms. Ford, a computer-aided designer and 17-year Kodak veteran, was snapped up by a
  1033. local contractor that gets much of its work from Kodak. "I took the project I was working on
  1034. and finished it here," she says. But instead of paying her $15 an hour plus benefits, Kodak
  1035. now pays the contractor $65 an hour, and Ms. Ford earns $20 an hour (but gets no benefits).
  1036. Kodak's layoffs have left its engineering group in Rochester, N.Y., overworked and
  1037. demoralized, Ms. Ford contends. "They're burned out and they don't even care. When they
  1038. send a job over here and we say, `It's going to cost you X,' they just say `Go ahead,'" she
  1039. says....
  1040. At my own employer, a hospital, management has imposed several waves of drastic
  1041. downsizing: of nursing staff, physical/occupational therapists, and respiratory techs,
  1042. among other job categories. And guess what? First of all, they have suffered horribly
  1043. from the bad word of mouth in the surrounding community, thanks to the deterioration of
  1044. quality in patient care. Second, exactly as with Kodak, they wound up actually paying
  1045. more in staffing costs than they were before. The hospital pays for travel RNs from a
  1046. staffing agency, with the agency's fee probably over $100/hour, sometimes to do the job
  1047. of an orderly. It has contracted a husband-wife team of respiratory techs, high-paid travel
  1048. workers, from a staffing agency. Last December, half the physical and occupational
  1049. therapists on the rehab ward where I work gave notice, because a local nursing home paid
  1050. therapists several bucks an hour more and had better working conditions. As a result, the
  1051. hospital was forced to cap the ward's census at twelve patients for several months, and to
  1052. run it at even that capacity had to hire highly-paid therapists from a staffing agency. The
  1053. going agency fee for medical staff is typically three times the wage of a permanent
  1054. employee, with the agency worker making about 150% the wage of those working inhouse; so their attempt to "cut costs" through understaffing and skimping on pay caused
  1055. them to pay three times as much to replace the staff they downsized or drove off through
  1056. uncompetitive pay. This doesn't even touch on the costs from abysmal employee morale,
  1057. on wards where one orderly often has twenty or thirty patients, from the skyrocketing
  1058. rates of absenteeism among nursing staff who dread coming to work under such
  1059. conditions, and the very high rates of turnover and costs of training replacements.
  1060. But the damage to an organization's human capital, Markels and Murray continue,
  1061. goes far beyond the mere cost of replacing staff:
  1062. Despite warnings about downsizing becoming dumbsizing, many companies continue to
  1063. make flawed decisions -- hasty, across-the-board cuts -- that come back to haunt them, on the
  1064. bottom line, in public relations, in strained relationships with customers and suppliers, and in
  1065. demoralized employees. Sweeping early-retirement and buyout programs sometimes
  1066. eliminate not only the deadwood but the talented, many of whom head straight to
  1067. competitors. Meanwhile, many replacements arrive knowing little about the company and
  1068. soon repeat their predecessors' mistakes.
  1069. "Cost-cutting has become the holy grail of corporate management," says Rick Maurer, an
  1070. Arlington, Va., management consultant. "But what helps the financial statement up front can
  1071. end up hurting it down the road."
  1072. In Digital Equipment Corp.'s 1994 reorganization, its second in as many years, the
  1073. company eliminated hundreds of sales and marketing jobs in its health-industries group,
  1074. which had been bringing in $800 million of annual revenue by selling computers to hospitals
  1075. and other health-care providers world-wide.
  1076. Digital says it cut because it had to act fast. It was losing about $3 million a day, and its
  1077. cost of sales was much higher than that of its rivals. Robert B. Palmer, the chief executive
  1078. officer of the Maynard, Mass., company, saw across-the-board cuts in all units, regardless of
  1079. profitability, as the way to go. Indeed, Digital has reported profits for the past five quarters
  1080. and has positioned itself for future growth by forming alliances with Microsoft Corp. and
  1081. other software vendors.
  1082. But in the health-industries group, the cutbacks imposed unexpected costs. Digital
  1083. disrupted longstanding ties between its veteran salespeople and major customers by
  1084. transferring their accounts to new sales divisions. It also switched hundreds of smaller
  1085. accounts to outside distributors without notifying the customers.
  1086. At the industry's annual conference, "I had customers coming up to me and saying, `I
  1087. haven't seen a Digital sales rep in nine months. Whom do I talk to now?'" recalls Joseph
  1088. Lesica, a former marketing manager in the group who resigned last year. "That really hurt
  1089. our credibility. I was embarrassed."
  1090. Resellers of Digital computers, who account for most of its health-care sales, also
  1091. complained about diminished technology and sales support. "There were months when you
  1092. couldn't find anybody with a Digital badge," complains an official at one former reseller who
  1093. had been accustomed to Digital sales reps accompanying him on some customer calls. "They
  1094. walked away from large numbers of clients." Adds Richard Tarrant, chief executive of IDX
  1095. Systems Corp., a Burlington, Vt., reseller that used to have an exclusive arrangement with
  1096. Digital: "Now, they're just one of several vendors we use."
  1097. Many Digital customers turned to International Business Machines Corp. and HewlettPackard Co., and so did some employees of Digital's downsized healthcare group. Mr. Lesica
  1098. says some laid-off workers went to Hewlett-Packard and quickly set about bringing Digital
  1099. clients with them. "That's another way DEC shot itself in the foot," he says.
  1100. Such wounds aren't unusual when longtime sales relationships are disrupted. "Nobody
  1101. sits down and asks, `What's going to be the impact on our customers?'" says D. Quinn Mills,
  1102. a Harvard Business School professor. "It falls between the cracks all the time."...
  1103. The question is, to what extent are [payroll] savings offset by the new hires' lack of
  1104. experience? Ms. Shapiro, the consultant, contends that a company is set back severely by the
  1105. loss of "knowledge and judgment earned over the years. That's the stuff that gives you a real
  1106. competitive advantage in the long run." Human-resources experts estimate that it typically
  1107. costs $50,000 to recruit and train a managerial or technical worker....
  1108. Others try to reduce employment costs by replacing experienced veterans with less
  1109. expensive contract workers. But that can heighten a company's chances of being represented
  1110. by people who perform poorly -- or worse. That's what happened at Peoples Natural Gas Co.,
  1111. which hoped to save more than $1 million last year by replacing its 35 meter readers with
  1112. contract workers. "We thought we would be able to get the same quality by outsourcing as
  1113. we would with our own employees," says Elmore Lockley, a spokesman.
  1114. But on March 19, one of the new meter readers allegedly raped a Peoples Gas customer
  1115. while on a call. Overnight, the Pittsburgh company faced "a major challenge, not only from a
  1116. public-relations standpoint but from a human-tragedy standpoint," Mr. Lockley says....
  1117. Nynex's early-out programs for managers and craft-level employees, which have trimmed
  1118. about 12,000 jobs since 1993, have caused labor shortages as well. Nynex has hired back
  1119. hundreds of former employees, including managers already receiving pensions....
  1120. Even greater than the rehiring expense is the blight on Nynex's reputation for customer
  1121. service -- right when its core market is opening up to competition for the first time. "Their
  1122. past reputation for customer service is their key competitive advantage," says Joe Kraemer, a
  1123. management consultant at the A.T. Kearney subsidiary of Electronic Data Systems Inc. in
  1124. Rosslyn, Va. "But they've put all that at risk, just to gain a few cents per share in a given
  1125. quarter. It's just plain dumb."65
  1126. As Charles Derber put it, "[c]ontract workers are usually clueless about inside
  1127. knowledge specific to the firm, and lack key social ties in and out of the company
  1128. necessary to close deals and maintain relations to customers.66
  1129. Self-serving management policies undermine the trust which is required for workers
  1130. to invest their human capital in the enterprise. Gary Miller, in The Political Economy of
  1131. Hierarchy, argues that trust is the main distinguishing feature of firms that make the most
  1132. productive use of human capital. He cites work in behavioral economics and game theory
  1133. on how relationships of trust are built up through repeated interactions, when the parties
  1134. know they will be dealing with each other in the future. The lesson for the firm, in
  1135. particular, is illustrated by piece rates. In the short run, management may have a rational
  1136. incentive to elicit greater effort through piecework pay, and then cutting piece rates. But
  1137. in the long run, it will only be possible to elicit greater effort if workers are confident that
  1138. management will not change the rules of the game to screw them over; otherwise, the
  1139. rational strategy for workers is deliberate shirking combined with social sanctions against
  1140. ratebusters. Management can elicit greater effort through prolonged confidence-building
  1141. measures to demonstrate, in a credible manner, their lack of intent to expropriate the
  1142. 65
  1143. Alex Markels and Matt Murray, "Call It Dumbsizing: Why Some Companies Regret Cost-Cutting," Wall
  1144. Street Journal, May 14, 1996 <http://www.markels.com/management.htm>.
  1145. 66
  1146. Charlers Derber, Corporation Nation: How Corporations are Taking Over Our Lives and What We Can
  1147. Do About It (New York: St. Martin's Griffin, 1998), pp. 111-112.
  1148. productivity gains of greater effort. To generalize beyond piece rates, management can
  1149. only elicit workers' investment of their human capital in the productivity of the enterprise
  1150. by giving them long-term property rights in their share of productivity gains, with
  1151. credible safeguards against expropriation.67
  1152. Unfortunately, Miller continues, because such cooperative cultures are established by
  1153. "mutually reinforcing expectations," they are highly dependent on "the beliefs of the
  1154. various players about the likely responses of other players." That means that they are
  1155. extremely fragile when one party acts to undermine trust. He illustrates the lesson with a
  1156. case study of an Indiana gypsum mine in the 1950s. The management had an informal
  1157. and egalitarian relationship with the workers, and generally showed up in work clothes.
  1158. The management style was extremely lax about things like clocking in late or clocking
  1159. out early, sick days, etc., and relied heavily on employee initiative and motivation in
  1160. solving problems without micromanagement. The work force was willing to pull long
  1161. hours of overtime in emergencies; rather than hoarding their tacit knowledge, they were
  1162. willing to invest it in increasing productivity.
  1163. A new Pharaoh arose, however, who knew not Joseph. When the old plant manager
  1164. died, his replacement was a Barney Fife type who was horrified at the lax enforcement of
  1165. rules. He strictly enforced clock-in and clock-out times, hired foremen who would
  1166. micromanage production and treat thinking as a management prerogative, and generally
  1167. instituted an adversarial culture.
  1168. Of course, the workers responded in kind. They decided that, if management was
  1169. going to stand on the rules, they would do the same. Remarking on the new "zero
  1170. tolerance" time clock policy, one worker said:
  1171. Well, if that's the way he wants it, that's the way he wants it. But I'll be damned if I put in
  1172. any overtime when things get rough and they'd like us to.
  1173. O.K., I'll punch in just so, and I'll punch out on the nose. But you know you can lead a
  1174. horse to water and you can lead him away, but it's awful hard to tell how much water he
  1175. drinks while he's at it.68
  1176. All this is closely related to our discussion immediately above of human capital and
  1177. "dumbsizing." An organizational culture of cooperation and mutual trust is a very
  1178. important form of human capital--one that takes a great deal of time and effort to build
  1179. up, and can be destroyed overnight by the typical idiot MBA who thinks he can goose his
  1180. stock options by laying off half the work force.
  1181. One of the most important ways to safeguard a culture of trust is through confidence-
  1182. 67
  1183. Gary J. Miller, Managerial Dilemmas: The Political Economy of Hierarchy (New York: Cambridge
  1184. University Press, 1992), pp. 201-202.
  1185. 68
  1186. Ibid., pp. 207-210.
  1187. building measures, which make it more costly for management to defect and reassure the
  1188. workforce that the productivity gains from their investment of effort will not be
  1189. expropriated. This brings us back to the observations of Rajan and Zingales (which we
  1190. will see in Chapter Nine) on the importance of stakeholder equity rights in the
  1191. corporation.
  1192. Many firms that are most successful at encouraging high levels of commitment and nonmonitored effort from subordinates have effectively reallocated to employees some of the
  1193. property rights to the assets owned by the firm, creating a sense of what is significantly
  1194. called "employee ownership," or long-term control over those aspects of the workplace that
  1195. are most important to employees.69
  1196. This quote from Jeffrey Nielsen, which we already saw in Chapter Six, is worth
  1197. another look:
  1198. With rank-based logic, people see work as a burden and organization as a necessary evil.
  1199. We only grudgingly join up with organizations and then find life within them to be nasty,
  1200. boring, and deadening to the spirit.. When the organization encounters hardships, the
  1201. assumption is that those below should be sacrificed to protect the privilege of those above.
  1202. All too frequently we read in the financial section of the paper about this type of logic in
  1203. action: another CEO who laid off hundreds of workers is awarded with a fat bonus at the
  1204. end of the year.
  1205. Nielsen continued to write, directly after the material quoted above:
  1206. Author Jason Jennings, in a USA Today (2002) editorial, said that many leaders believe
  1207. downsizing in tough economic times is the right leadership thing to do. Citing a major 2002
  1208. research project of the Business Roundtable on the relationship between layoffs and
  1209. productivity, Jennings challenges this conventional wisdom. The research revealed that the
  1210. world's most productive firms make an explicit promise never to balance the books through
  1211. layoffs.70
  1212. But we must always keep in mind that "the right leadership thing to do," from the
  1213. perspective of leaders, is tacitly defined in terms of the private interest of those leaders. I
  1214. have no doubt that Jennings' preferred course of action is more effective by his standards
  1215. of productivity: increased sales, lower costs, and more profit per employee. But for
  1216. corporate management, the "productivity" of an organization means something entirely
  1217. different: the support of management in the lifestyle to which it is entitled. By way of
  1218. analogy, a self-managed cooperative would have been a vast improvement in productivity
  1219. for an ante-bellum cotton plantation. That is, it would have meant an improvement in
  1220. productivity in every measure except the one that mattered: from the perspective of the
  1221. slave-owner, eliciting effort from slaves is the most unproductive form of economic
  1222. 69
  1223. Ibid., p. 226.
  1224. Jeffrey Nielsen, The Myth of Leadership: Creating Leaderless Organizations (Palo Alto Calif.: DaviesBlack Publishing, 2004), p. 53.
  1225. 70
  1226. organization except for the alternative of looking for honest work. For management,
  1227. getting the most of a small pie is preferable to a smaller piece of a big pie; their goal is
  1228. not to maximize the size of the pie, but the size of their piece. We must never forget that
  1229. the real goal of the organization, from the perspective of management, is to serve
  1230. management; all that smarmy rhetoric in the mission statement is for outside
  1231. consumption. From management's perspective, it's hard to imagine an organization being
  1232. more "productive" than GE was for Welch or Home Depot was for Nardelli. While
  1233. Nielsen's peer-based organizations may be more productive for "everyone" (probably not
  1234. for Welch and Nardelli), the hierarchical organization is more productive for the people
  1235. who count.
  1236. We already saw, in Chapter Seven, how Robert Nardelli inflated Home Depot's shortterm profits by stripping it of productive assets. This is quite common in the
  1237. managerialist culture. Jackall described that culture from first-hand observation:
  1238. The growing dominance of new professional managers has helped emphasize the already
  1239. existing corporate premium on quick returns. In the process, it has placed a new premium on
  1240. fast deals and on money made in paper transactions rather than on the arduous and
  1241. necessarily long-term task of taking material out of the ground and creating wealth. Within
  1242. such a framework, plants and the whole production process become, as one manager notes,
  1243. "a bother"....
  1244. Moreover, the capital markets are increasingly dominated by big institutional investors-among them, large corporations, the insurance companies, the investment funds, and the
  1245. brokerage houses--whose "quick in, quick out" philosophy wreaks havoc with corporate
  1246. stocks. This sets the stage for financial sharpshooters who, in takeover strategies, buy large
  1247. chunks of a company's stock at devalued prices only to be "greenmailed" ...by the target
  1248. company's management into surrendering these blocks of holdings at premium prices. In
  1249. such unsettled times, where virtually any large corporation could become a takeover target,
  1250. managers feel that they have to keep their companies' stock properly valued.71
  1251. This pressure from the financial markets is reinforced by corporate pressure on
  1252. managers, who are evaluated on short-term results. Making correct decisions for longterm productivity may be politically disastrous; the effects will not be seen until long after
  1253. the decisionmaker is no longer around to take credit.72
  1254. General Motors is a good example of this tendency to strip corporations of productive
  1255. assets and turn them into hollow shells. As Eric Husman observed,73 GM has become,
  1256. increasingly, a company that brands, markets, and finances cars, rather than building
  1257. them. Their main source of profit is now GMAC, the auto sale finance arm of the
  1258. company. And if they turn a large profit in a given year, there's a good chance it's the
  1259. result of selling off another couple of plants.
  1260. 71
  1261. Jackall, Moral Mazes, p. 83.
  1262. Ibid., p. 84.
  1263. 73
  1264. See Chapter Ten.
  1265. 72
  1266. All these tendencies are reinforced, in American corporate culture, by the Sloan
  1267. management accounting system, which is described in unflattering clinical detail by
  1268. William Waddell and Norman Bodek in Rebirth of American Industry.74
  1269. Waddell and Bodek contrast the Sloan system to the Toyota Production System, or
  1270. lean manufacturing, which measures profitability by revenue stream. If there's more
  1271. money coming in this week than going out, the operation is profitable. Assets are of
  1272. interest only when applying for a loan or liquidating the enterprise. Inventory that isn't
  1273. bringing in real cash from outside is a cost, not an asset. The best way to reduce costs is
  1274. to fully utilize equipment and reduce cycle time through increased flow, to avoid waste
  1275. and rework through designing defects out of the production process rather than inspecting
  1276. for quality after the fact, and to minimize inventory through just-in-time production. And
  1277. these things are all achieved mainly with the help of the company's chief asset, its human
  1278. capital.
  1279. The Sloan system (or DuPont/Sloan/Brown system), on the other hand, attempts to
  1280. maximize Return on Investment (ROI), which translates into share value: i.e., the book
  1281. value of the company divided by the number of shares. The larger the sum that could be
  1282. raised by auctioning off the company's assets in the event of bankruptcy, the better
  1283. managed it was.75
  1284. Pierre DuPont devised a system to be sure that the salvage value of the companies in which
  1285. he invested was high. From one end of the country to another, GE and GM plants can be had
  1286. for salvage value.76
  1287. And corporate management's primary activity for the last twenty years has been living off
  1288. the salvage value of the organizations whose assets it has gutted.
  1289. Perversely, the Sloan system counts inventory toward this book value (a metric that
  1290. works directly at cross-purposes to the lean system, which treats inventory as a cost).
  1291. With inventory declared to be an asset with the same liquidity as cash, it did not really matter
  1292. whether the next "cost center," department, plant, or division actually needed the production
  1293. output right away in order to consummate one of these paper sales. The producing
  1294. department put the output into inventory and took credit.77
  1295. This is referred to as "overhead absorption," which means fully incorporating all
  1296. production costs into the price of goods "sold" to inventory, at which point they count as
  1297. 74
  1298. William H. Waddell and Norman Bodek, Rebirth of American Industry: A Study of Lean Management
  1299. (Vancouver, WA: PCS Press, 2005).
  1300. 75
  1301. Ibid., pp. 68-69.
  1302. 76
  1303. Ibid., p. 108.
  1304. 77
  1305. Ibid., p. 75.
  1306. an asset on the balance sheet.78 American factories frequently have warehouse shelves
  1307. filled with millions of dollars worth of obsolete inventory, which is still there "to avoid
  1308. having to reduce profits this quarter by writing it off."79
  1309. At the same time, it defines production labor as the primary "variable cost," so that all
  1310. "cost-cutting" and "efficiency" measures focus almost entirely on downsizing the labor
  1311. force. This, despite the ways that (as we saw above) human capital increases the
  1312. productivity of an organization--and the ways that, as we will see in Chapter Nine, human
  1313. capital increases the organization's book value. Yet other intangibles, like "goodwill" and
  1314. "intellectual property," are treated, oddly, as assets, on the grounds that they contribute to
  1315. book value. Since inventory is as good as cash, and management salaries are a fixed
  1316. rather than variable expense, management understandably filters out overhead when it
  1317. comes to finding ways to cut costs; the overall effect is that corporate management
  1318. automatically thinks of downsizing production workers, as the first and only alternative,
  1319. when it comes time to reduce costs.
  1320. Brown's contribution was primarily that he could take this definition of ROI, look out
  1321. over General Motors operations and envision islands of cost awash in a sea of assets. Those
  1322. islands of cost were basically people. Well-supervised, they could turn one form of
  1323. inventory into another with little of their time left over to detract from profits. Left
  1324. uncontrolled, however, they could waste a lot of money with nothing to show for it. So
  1325. "responsibility accounting" came to be, when each of those islands was deemed to be a cost
  1326. center, which added up to plants which added up to divisions which added up to corporate.80
  1327. ...While Sloan, Brown and the rest may have looked out over the plants and seen islands
  1328. of cost in a sea of assets, they knew that around the edges and lurking beneath the surface
  1329. there were other costs in the form of overhead. The problem was that these costs, such as the
  1330. costs of moving things around, fixing machines, inspecting parts, and supervising, were
  1331. awfully hard to assign to a specific operation. They went along with everything in general,
  1332. but nothing in particular. Without any means of directly assigning and controlling them,
  1333. these costs were simply assigned percentages in the hope that they would stay reasonably in
  1334. proportion to the direct labor costs which could be controlled, and that was good enough.
  1335. Without any direct link, all that could be measured with great confidence was the direct,
  1336. easy to correlate part of the job: labor. It did not take much of a mathematician to figure out
  1337. that, if all you really care about is the cost of performing one operation to a part, and you
  1338. were allowed to make money by doing that single operation as cheaply as possible and then
  1339. calling the partially complete product an asset, it would be cheaper to make them a bunch at
  1340. a time.
  1341. It stood to reason that spreading set-up costs over many parts was cheaper than having to
  1342. set-up for just a few even if it meant making more parts than you needed for a long time. It
  1343. also made sense, if you could make enough parts all at once, to just make them cheaply, and
  1344. 78
  1345. Ibid., pp. 135-141.
  1346. Ibid., p. 132.
  1347. 80
  1348. Ibid., p. 68
  1349. 79
  1350. then sort out the bad ones later.
  1351. Across the board, batches became the norm because the direct cost of batches was cheap
  1352. and they could be immediately turned into money--at least as far as Mr. DuPont was
  1353. concerned--by classifying them as work-in-process inventory.81
  1354. Or, to put it in more colorful terms, "the typical factory went from Ford's flowing
  1355. river of material to a Sloanesque oozing swamp..." The obsession with lowering direct
  1356. labor costs, and direct labor costs only, caused costs from correcting defects and storing
  1357. inventory to skyrocket. Not to mention recalls, which frequently run around half of total
  1358. production--for example, over 45 million from 1966 to 1975.82
  1359. H. Thomas Johnson and Robert S. Kaplan, in Relevance Lost, also discussed the
  1360. perverse effects of treating direct labor as the main source of cost. If a production
  1361. manager achieves savings in overhead costs, the savings are diluted over all the cost
  1362. centers in the factory because of the allocation procedure. "Therefore, rational managers
  1363. focus their attention where it does the most 'good'": direct labor. "Consequently, less
  1364. attention is devoted to escalating overhead costs than to small increments in labor costs."
  1365. This also creates a perverse incentive to outsource or offshore production of components
  1366. to take advantage of cheap labor, even though it only affects the cost of direct labor which
  1367. may be relatively minor compared to the part of factory overhead not driven by direct
  1368. labor, and therefore "saves only a relatively small fraction of the component's costs." In
  1369. fact, the transaction costs involved in subcontracting tend to increase overhead costs.
  1370. "But these newly added costs are not traced to the purchased component because it has
  1371. zero direct labor content. Instead, the higher overhead costs are shifted to the laborintense products and processes still remaining in the plant."83
  1372. David F. Noble discussed the same phenomenon in Progress Without People,
  1373. referring to the standard accounting practice of measuring productivity in terms of "output
  1374. per person-hour.":
  1375. An overriding assumption of almost all discussion about automation is that productivity
  1376. increases result from the subordination of machines for hourly production workers. That is,
  1377. a reduction in factory jobs is ipso facto understood to mean a gain in productivity.... [But],
  1378. as Thomas Gunn argued in 1982, "Direct labor accounts for only ten to twenty-five percent
  1379. of the total cost of manufacturing....
  1380. John Simpson, Director of Manufacturing Engineering at the National Bureau of
  1381. Standards, took this same message a bit further: "In metalworking manufacture, direct labor
  1382. amounts to roughly 10 percent of total cost, as opposed to materials at 55 percent and
  1383. 81
  1384. Ibid., p. 98.
  1385. Langdon Winner, The Whale and the Reactor: A Search for Limits in an Age of High Technology
  1386. (Chicago and London: University of Chicago Press, 1986), p. 77.
  1387. 83
  1388. H. Thomas Johnson and Robert S. Kaplan, Relevance Lost: The Rise and Fall of Management
  1389. Accounting (Boston: Harvard Business School Press, 1987), pp. 188-189.
  1390. 82
  1391. overhead another 35 percent. Yet, as of 1982, management was expending roughly 75
  1392. percent of managerial and engineering effort on labor costs reduction, as compared to 15
  1393. percent on material cost reduction and 10 percent on overhead cost reduction. This is a
  1394. striking disparity."
  1395. It certainly is. As Business Week discovered in its 1982 survey of executives, few
  1396. managers anticipated much use of the new equipment to displace management, even though
  1397. such reduction in overhead, as Simpson suggests, would no doubt serve the goal of increased
  1398. productivity.84
  1399. In my own experience, the obsession with cutting patient care staff as a "variable
  1400. cost" in most hospitals (especially after the corporate chains take them over) leads to the
  1401. phenomena described in the fourth section of Appendix 8A of this chapter. Costs from
  1402. patient falls, hospital-acquired infections, and errors, as a direct result of understaffing,
  1403. rise until they more than offset the ostensible labor cost savings. The gutting of human
  1404. capital ("dumbsizing") described earlier in this section drastically reduces the quality of
  1405. care, and the effect is further exacerbated by disgruntlement and low morale among those
  1406. who are left to handle the workload. Hospitals are even forced to turn away patients
  1407. (what is called "diversion mode") for want of sufficient staff to care for them. As a result,
  1408. they suffer catastrophic losses to their reputations and lose business. This is the direct,
  1409. inevitable result of treating human capital, which takes years to build up and years to
  1410. acquire its network of human relationships and distributed knowledge, as a "variable
  1411. cost" to be fired and rehired as often as demand shifts--and meanwhile treating
  1412. management as a fixed expense to be paid in both fat times and lean.
  1413. As we will see in the next chapter, human and organizational capital--the human
  1414. relationships, trust, and tacit knowledge of processes that take years to build up, and
  1415. cannot be rebuilt in a short time at any cost--are the reason a firm's equity is greater than
  1416. the book value of its tangible assets. It really is capital, and a productive asset. As we
  1417. saw above, "dumbsizing" disrupts and mutilates this human capital, and guts an
  1418. organization's long-term productive capability. But the Sloan system treats labor as "the
  1419. biggest profit detractor [a] company [has]..."85 The Sloan system's "arrogant and
  1420. demeaning" approach to people "assured that employee involvement in production would
  1421. not happen."86
  1422. Direct labor is not a variable cost as a result of some mystic truth or a law of either
  1423. nature or physics. It is a variable cost because management decided it would be so. Calling
  1424. inventory an asset, while people are not an asset is also a distortion of the truth.87
  1425. For this reason, the right-wingers and corporate apologists in this country who spend
  1426. 84
  1427. David F. Noble, Progress Without People: New Technology, Unemployment, and the Message of
  1428. Resistance (Toronto: Between the Lines, 1995), p. 105.
  1429. 85
  1430. Waddell and Bodek, p. 152.
  1431. 86
  1432. Ibid., p. 153.
  1433. 87
  1434. Ibid., p. 207.
  1435. so much time tisk-tisking about Japanese "lifetime employment guarantees" miss the
  1436. point. The irony is that the people who are quickest to observe that "nobody washes a
  1437. rental car," in regard to the benefits of and "ownership society" outside the workplace, are
  1438. the same idiots who complain the most about the evils of job security inside the
  1439. workplace.
  1440. "Lifetime employment" is just another way of saying the Japanese treat human capital
  1441. as an asset rather than a direct cost, which is precisely the lesson we learned above from
  1442. Waddell and Bodek. Employment security builds trust, and hence human capital, by
  1443. reassuring workers that they have a secure property right in their contributions to
  1444. productivity, that the productivity gains they create won't be expropriated by
  1445. management, and that their increased effort and productivity won't be used against them
  1446. through rate-busting, speedups and downsizing. It elicits the kind of behavior that Rajan
  1447. and Zingales describe: workers investing their human capital in the productivity of the
  1448. enterprise. To quote William Ouchi,
  1449. The first lesson of Theory Z is trust. Productivity and trust go hand in hand, strange as it
  1450. may seem....
  1451. ...Thomas Lifson... has studied in detail the Japanese general trading firms, those firms
  1452. like Mitsui, Mitsubishi, and Sumitomo that maintain offices worldwide and have
  1453. traditionally served as the sales force for Japanese-produced goods.... According to Lifson,
  1454. the central feature of the [Japanese] trading firm is an extensive management system that
  1455. maintains a sense of trust between employees in the trading company.... [The employees]
  1456. work in an environment of tremendous uncertainty, buying and selling copper ore, crude oil,
  1457. wheat and televisions.... Often, the firm's overall profitability will be maximized if an office
  1458. takes a loss, which will be more than made up in another office so that the company benefits
  1459. overall. The success of the trading company depends critically upon the willingness of
  1460. individual offices and employees to make these sacrifices. That willingness exists because
  1461. the Japanese trading firm uses managerial practices that foster trust through the knowledge
  1462. that such sacrifices will always be repaid in the future....
  1463. One American company that has a definite uniqueness but at the same time resembles the
  1464. Japanese management style is Hewlett-Packard.88
  1465. The problem, for the right-wingers, is probably that "increasing productivity" is
  1466. something the John Galts do, while workers are passive dullards who contribute nothing
  1467. to the production process. An extreme example of this is George Reisman, who
  1468. continually rewrites the same article at Mises.Org: the only way to increase the worker's
  1469. standard of living is to increase the wealth of the capitalist, who invests his capital in
  1470. increasing the worker's productivity, which drives up wages. The concept of human
  1471. capital, or the possibility (as we saw in Chapters Two, Five and Seven) that the worker's
  1472. unique knowledge of how best to employ existing physical capital matters more to
  1473. 88
  1474. William Ouchi, Theory Z: How American Business Can Meet the Japanese Challenge (New York:
  1475. Avon Books, 1981), pp.5-6. Ouchi wrote, obviously, before Carly Fiorina destroyed "the HP Way."
  1476. productivity than the amount of capital employed, is lost on such people. If the reader
  1477. suspects me of exaggeration, consider these quotes, first from Mises himself and then
  1478. from Reisman:
  1479. You have the courage to tell the masses what no politician told them: you are inferior
  1480. and all the improvements in your conditions which you simply take for granted you owe to
  1481. the effort of men who are better than you.89
  1482. Carson is simply unaware that innovation is the product of exceptional, dedicated
  1483. individuals who must overcome the uncomprehending dullness of most of their fellows, and
  1484. often their hostility as well.90
  1485. One of the most interesting proposals for countering this perverse treatment of human
  1486. capital as a cost is the idea of "human resource accounting." It came out of a research
  1487. project which Rensis Likert (mentioned above) inspired, at the University of Michigan's
  1488. Institute for Social Research, aimed at correlating management styles to profitability.
  1489. The idea is to transform the management bromide that "employees are our most valuable
  1490. asset" from a mere hypocritical slogan into reality, and develop a metric for counting the
  1491. actual equity value of human capital toward the bottom line.
  1492. The Michigan team has laid out three basic approaches to the problem, by computing
  1493. figures for (1) the value of investments in human resources (approximately corresponding to
  1494. book value for physical assets); (2) replacement values; and (3) economic values, that is, the
  1495. capitalized value of earnings directly attributable to these resources.
  1496. A good start has been made on the first two, which include "expenditures in recruiting,
  1497. hiring, training, developing, and organizing employees into effective work groups...." Since
  1498. 1966, the R. G. Barry Corp.... has been developing, with the help of the Michigan team,
  1499. methods of calculating these figures. By 1970, "book value" figures had been computed for
  1500. all 147 managers in the company and 425 factory and clerical personnel....
  1501. In 1969, Barry drew up, for internal use, a "capital budget for human resources,"
  1502. believed to be the first of its kind, which can answer questions in such areas as new
  1503. expenditures for training programs, the real costs of employee turnover, and whether the
  1504. human resources in any particular department are rising or falling. In this way, if any
  1505. manager attempts to juice up short-term profits at the expense of company resources, top
  1506. management will be alerted immediately.... [The 1969 annual report showed] that, because of
  1507. heavy employee-development costs (which, logically, might be better capitalized than
  1508. expensed), reported earnings were understated by about 10 percent, and that when "net
  1509. investments in human resources" were added to the asset side of the balance sheet, total
  1510. 89
  1511. Mises' letter to Ayn Rand, quoted in Bettina Bien Greaves, "To What Extent Was Rand a Misesian?"
  1512. Mises.Org, April 11, 2005 <http://mises.org/story/1790>.
  1513. 90
  1514. George Reisman, "Freedom is Slavery: Laissez-Faire Capitalism is Government Invasion: A Critique of
  1515. Kevin Carson's Studies in Mutualist Political Economy," The Journal of Libertarian Studies 20:1 (Winter
  1516. 2006), p. 55.
  1517. assets rose by some 15 percent.91
  1518. The Sloan system is at the heart of the American MBA curriculum, and the ruling
  1519. paradigm in American corporate governance.
  1520. As leader of a Dana Corporation management study group visiting Japan, Bodek-who had been a frequent visitor to the country for many years and had become familiar
  1521. with the Toyota Production System--let slip that he considered the ROI a faulty measure
  1522. that Dana should abandon.
  1523. You would think that I just allowed the dam to break. Virtually every manager on the bus
  1524. shot me down and made me feel like two cents. In one short moment I lost all credibility
  1525. with them. The Japanese managers taught me that ROI was misleading because it leads you
  1526. to focus only on the short-term, to the long-term detriment of the company.
  1527. A few months later, Woody Morcott, the next chairman of Dana, keynoted one of my
  1528. Productivity "The American Way" conferences and told the audience that ROI was key, and
  1529. the only important measure for his managers. I knew then why I had been so quickly shot
  1530. down in Japan.92
  1531. Sloan cost metrics, which focus almost entirely on reducing the "direct cost" of labor
  1532. involved in every operation, have seriously skewed the direction of production
  1533. technology.
  1534. ...[M]anufacturing engineers... were directed more and more to focus only on direct
  1535. labor savings. Machines that were more accurate or flexible could not be justified in
  1536. a batch environment. Where Ford's engineers built machines to speed flow and assure
  1537. quality, American engineers were pushed more and more into focusing on labor
  1538. elimination technology.93
  1539. As an illustration of the Sloan system's obsession with reducing the cost of every
  1540. operation, regardless of its effect on the overall production process, was illustrated by the
  1541. conversational stalemate between Ernie Breech (whom Eleanor Ford brought in in 1946
  1542. to impose GM methods on Ford) and a Ford manufacturing manager. Breech demanded
  1543. to know the cost of mounting steering wheels, attempting to figure the "profit" resulting
  1544. from steering wheel assembly independent of its necessary role in the overall
  1545. manufacturing process.
  1546. The production manager didn't know how much the specific operation cost, and was
  1547. utterly perplexed as to why Breech wanted to know. Was Breech suggesting the steering
  1548. wheel assembly operation was the source of a bottleneck in the flow of the line? No.
  1549. 91
  1550. Jenkins, Job Power, pp. 238-240.
  1551. Waddell and Bodek, p. 65.
  1552. 93
  1553. Ibid., p. 106.
  1554. 92
  1555. Was there some inefficiency in the operation? No. Since it had to be done, and done
  1556. right, it could only be considered as part of the overall process. And the only proper way
  1557. to increase efficiency, and reduce costs, was to lower unit costs by improving the flow of
  1558. the overall process.
  1559. The lean accounting companies define making money as receiving cash. Incremental
  1560. work is not good--it is a waste of money.... Money is made only by selling to customers, not
  1561. by transferring dollars between accounts or by moving parts from one inventory pile to
  1562. another.94
  1563. Between the accounting people Breech brought in from GM, and the "whiz kids" Bob
  1564. McNamara brought in from the war department, Ford was cured of that kind of
  1565. thinking.95
  1566. Interestingly, the mostly uneducated workers of recuperated enterprises in Argentina,
  1567. forced to use their own common sense after the managers and accountants abandoned the
  1568. plants, spontaneously rediscovered Ford's system of cash flow accounting on their own.
  1569. How did these men (none of whom have a university degree and most of whom do not
  1570. even have a high school diploma) administer, manage, market, and run nothing less than an
  1571. entire factory in the complex reality of today's market, economy, and finances?
  1572. We wanted to go with a very small-time economy. Nothing complicated. Buy this, sell
  1573. that, this much is left, and that's it.96
  1574. The Sloan system focuses, exclusively, on labor savings "perceived to be attainable
  1575. only through faster machines. Never mind that faster machines build inventory faster, as
  1576. well."97 As the authors of Natural Capitalism argue, batch production results from
  1577. attempts to optimize each separate step of the production process in isolation
  1578. ("optimizing one element in isolation from others and thereby pessimizing the entire
  1579. system"), without regard to its effect on the flow of the overall production process. A
  1580. machine can reduce the labor cost of one step, by running at enormous speeds, and yet be
  1581. out of sync with the overall process, so that it simply produces excess inventory that waits
  1582. to be used by the next step in the process.98 The giant cola-canning machine and Pratt &
  1583. Whitney's robotic grinders, which we saw in Chapter Two, are good examples. The
  1584. Toyota Production System, on the other hand, emphasizes takt: pacing the output of each
  1585. stage of production to meet the needs of the next stage, and coordinating all of the stages
  1586. in accordance with current orders.99
  1587. 94
  1588. Ibid., p. 92.
  1589. Ibid., pp. 89-90.
  1590. 96
  1591. The Lavaca Collective, Sin Patron: Stories from Argentina's Worker-Run Factories. Translated by
  1592. Katherine Kohlstedt (Chicago: Haymarket Books, 2007), p. 190
  1593. 97
  1594. Waddell and Bodek, p. 119.
  1595. 98
  1596. Hawken et al, Natural Capitalism, pp. 129-30.
  1597. 99
  1598. Waddell and Bodek, pp. 122-123.
  1599. 95
  1600. As Waddell and Bodek argue, lean production isn't primarily a matter of shop floor
  1601. organization. Shop floor organization, rather, tends to follow automatically from the
  1602. incentives the management accounting system puts in place.
  1603. However the accounting system is set up, it defines "making money" for the company
  1604. and becomes the basis for all decision making. The quality system, production and inventory
  1605. control systems and policies, people policies and so forth are all structured to enable the
  1606. company to make the most money. How these systems are structured is a direct result of
  1607. how the management of the company defines making money.
  1608. ....Early Ford and later Toyota defined money in a lean accounting manner and lean
  1609. practices resulted. General Motors defined making money as optimizing ROI and we all
  1610. know the practices that arose as a result. Henry Ford and the Toyoda family did not
  1611. personally go out and implement assembly lines or kanbans any more than Alfred Sloan went
  1612. out and personally created batch production. These men defined 'profitability' for their
  1613. companies, then urged and pushed their organizations to aggressively and creatively attain
  1614. that version of profitability.100
  1615. Success, in lean terms, barely shows up as such by Sloan metrics. Of the United
  1616. Defense plant in Aberdeen, South Dakota (one of the few American lean experiments that
  1617. actually "got" the Toyota system), Waddell and Bodek write:
  1618. A balance sheet prepared according to DuPont would miss the value of the plant in
  1619. Aberdeen entirely. According to the statistics in the most recent Best Manufacturing
  1620. Practices award from the Navy, inventory is down 78% from where it was just a few years
  1621. ago, and it was low by industry standards to begin with. A balance sheet, however, would
  1622. not reflect that as much of an accomplishment. The same balance sheet would assign no
  1623. value to the 150 cross-trained,, self-directed, customer-focused employees who generate very
  1624. profitable, sustained manufacturing results.101
  1625. Indeed, most American companies would lay half of them whenever business slowed
  1626. down, warn the remaining workers to work hard to pick up the slack (with a little Fish!
  1627. Philosophy and a catchy new core values statement thrown in to jolly them into enjoying
  1628. being screwed), and figure they could hire more help from a temp agency when things
  1629. picked up.
  1630. But "imagine," Waddell and Bodek write, a software or tech company declaring that
  1631. "computer science is a commodity--"
  1632. basically any warm body from the local temp agency can do it--and that the key to success in
  1633. running these technology companies is not technology, but finance and marketing. Imagine
  1634. further that they all but declare war on their programmers and system design folks,
  1635. 100
  1636. 101
  1637. Ibid., pp. 92-93.
  1638. Ibid., p. 159.
  1639. classifying them as variable costs and devising a management system aimed directly at
  1640. cutting their numbers and minimizing their pay.102
  1641. Sloan and Brown were dead wrong. Peole are not interchangeable commodities, to be
  1642. fired and laid off every time the wind blows from a different direction. Manufacturing is too
  1643. complicated; there are far too many variables. There is no computer big enough or fast
  1644. enough to plan and control it. Toyota knows this It takes a factory full of trained, focused,
  1645. committed people to get all of the details right in the midst of so many dynamic events. They
  1646. are not commodities.
  1647. A new accountant can be hired and pretty much become as effective as he or she is going
  1648. to get within a month or two. A production employee is more likely to take six months or
  1649. more--a year according to the self-directed teams at United Defense. Yet the accountant is a
  1650. fixed expense with a fair amount of job security, while the production worker is a
  1651. commodity.
  1652. ....The best way to develop the work force quickly and increase balance sheet accuracy
  1653. for the sake of the investor is to capitalize the cost of training and educating people....
  1654. Only in the world of F. W. Taylor, Pierre DuPont, Alfred Sloan and Donaldson Brown
  1655. can kicking trained, experienced, capable people out of a company be seen as a positive
  1656. move. There is nothing positive about it. It is proof of a basic failure of management. To do
  1657. so within months of paying the top manager better than $10 million in performance bonuses
  1658. ought to be proof enough that the system is broken.
  1659. To anticipated objections, from those steeped in the Sloan management culture, to
  1660. capitalizing an intangible like human capital, Waddell and Bodek respond, "[t]hat has
  1661. never stopped the Sloan companies from capitalizing goodwill and intellectual property,
  1662. often on far shakier ground than capitalizing people."103
  1663. One thing Waddell and Bodek fail to pick up on, perhaps being more charitable than I
  1664. am, is how incredibly well the Sloan system's cost and profit metrics dovetail with the
  1665. class interests of management. If management is simply a fixed cost to be paid in both
  1666. lean times and bad, but production work is a "direct cost" to be minimized and constantly
  1667. adjusted--by layoffs and firings--to the current level of demand, management (not
  1668. surprisingly) are the last to lose their jobs or suffer pay cuts. The metrics of the Sloan
  1669. system coincide so closely with management's pecuniary and careerist motives, in fact,
  1670. that it's a bit of a chicken and egg problem figuring out whether American managerialism
  1671. as it currently exists results from the Sloan system's incentives, or the Sloan system was
  1672. adopted because American management found it so conducive to their interests. There's
  1673. probably a mutual synergy involved.
  1674. Waddell and Bodek do see the implications of the system very clearly, however, even
  1675. 102
  1676. 103
  1677. Ibid., p. 223.
  1678. Ibid., pp. 240-242.
  1679. if they don't see how well it reinforces management venality.
  1680. It is so commonly accepted in the United States that direct labor is a variable cost that
  1681. the consequences of this arbitrary decision are rarely appreciated. At the top of the hierarchy
  1682. are the policy makers, strategists and those charged with controlling the factories. Their
  1683. salaries are a fixed cost, which means their jobs are relatively safe regardless of business
  1684. results, within a broad reasonable range. In the middle are manufacturing management
  1685. whose jobs have been, as a result of refinements to the cost accounting system, categorized
  1686. as semi-fixed or step function costs. Their jobs are only secure to a point. At the bottom are
  1687. Taylor's workers who should have no input to how things are made. They should be
  1688. expected to simply produce to the maximum efficiency. Their jobs are purely variable,
  1689. meaning their job security is purely a function of sales volume.
  1690. Those variable cost people--the ones Taichi Ohno points out are not even whole people
  1691. in American cost accounting--are not people at all. They are "headcount". That simple fact
  1692. makes lean manufacturing virtually impossible in Sloan companies. Lifetime employment,
  1693. such as that at Toyota, is nothing more than changing the system to categorize production
  1694. labor as a fixed expense.104
  1695. Just about every company says they want their people to work smarter not harder. Few
  1696. of them understand that people cannot and will not work smarter when they have supervisors
  1697. and industrial engineers hovering over them dictating and measuring their every move. They
  1698. especially will not work harder if management has defined the ultimate goal to be a lights out
  1699. factory, while they soar like hawks over the plant hunting for jobs to eliminate and people to
  1700. lay off. People everywhere will work smarter and harder for the customer, but people will
  1701. not work harder for someone who has defined them as a variable cost.105
  1702. Contrast this to the Japanese approach, as described by W. Edwards Deming
  1703. based on his experiences in Japanese industry.
  1704. In Japan, when a company has to absorb a sudden economic hardship such as a 25 per
  1705. cent decline in sales, the sacrificial pecking order is firmly set. First the corporate dividends
  1706. are cut. Then the salaries and the bonuses of top management are reduced. Next,
  1707. management salaries are trimmed from the top to the middle of the hierarchy. Lastly, the
  1708. rank and file are asked to accept pay cuts or a reduction in the work force through attrition or
  1709. voluntary discharge. In the United States, a typical firm would probably do the opposite
  1710. under similar circumstances [except for the relative priority of dividends and management
  1711. pay, of course--KC]."106
  1712. To the usual suspects at the Wall Street Journal and on CNBC money programs, it
  1713. goes without saying that the Toyota approach is wrong-headed. It makes perfect sense to
  1714. pay Bob "Sucks at Job" Nardelli or "Chainsaw Al" Dunlap a multi-million salary for all
  1715. 104
  1716. Ibid., p. 153.
  1717. Ibid., p. 158.
  1718. 106
  1719. W. Edwards Deming, Out of the Crisis (Cambridge, Mass.: M.I.T., Center for Advanced Engineering
  1720. Study, 1986), p. 147.
  1721. 105
  1722. that "productivity." But guaranteeing lifetime employment to production workers--to the
  1723. host organism rather than the parasite--is just plain wrong. As the analyst community's
  1724. reaction to Costco demonstrates, even if you can afford to pay good wages and provide
  1725. job security, it falls into the same moral category--vaguely decadent things that just don't
  1726. seem right--as putting a diamond collar on a dog. Such pampering makes companies
  1727. "bloated," "fat," and "lazy," don't you know!
  1728. Never mind that the Toyota approach to lifetime employment is perfectly consistent
  1729. with their understanding of the importance of painstakingly acquired human capital as a
  1730. source of organizational value. And never mind that it works. For example, John
  1731. Micklethwaite reports, before a Range Rover factory made a lifetime employment pledge
  1732. in the early '90s, only 11% of employees entered the annual employee suggestions
  1733. competition, "because they were worried that increased efficiency might cost them their
  1734. jobs; afterward the proportion rose to 84 percent." And a single one of those proposals
  1735. saved the company 100 million pounds.107
  1736. When employees are a fixed cost, the source of their job security is plant profitability.
  1737. When employees are a variable cost, they find job security by assuring that the work is never
  1738. complete. Lean companies outperform Sloan companies because profits are in the best
  1739. interests of the production employees in lean companies. It is hard to imagine how Sloan and
  1740. Brown could have expected a system to work that polarized workers and management so
  1741. thoroughly.108
  1742. But again, never mind. What matters is that no decent person puts a diamond collar
  1743. on a dog, and no decent company (despite all the Official Happy Talk about "teamwork"
  1744. and "our most valuable asset") actually treats its production workers like valuable assets.
  1745. You don't take money from starving kids to pamper a dog, and you don't take money from
  1746. Nardelli or Welch to pay production workers a living wage. It doesn't matter whether it's
  1747. profitable; it's a matter of decency. And in any case, when management is the de facto
  1748. owner of the corporation and runs it in its own interests, it's obviously not going to hurt
  1749. its own interests for the sake of productivity. It may fake productivity to game its stock
  1750. options, but it won't attempt the real thing when it requires treating workers like human
  1751. beings.
  1752. Sarcasm aside, the difference in companies like Toyota may have something to do
  1753. with our discussion of managerialism and the corporate form at the beginning of this
  1754. chapter. I argued there that while the idea of shareholder ownership, as a legitimating
  1755. ideology, did not reflect any actual shareholder control over management, it did play into
  1756. management's hands by insulating them from internal stakeholder control. American
  1757. corporate management, by pretending to be constrained by their duty to shareholders, can
  1758. actually promote their own interests without interference. Toyota, on the other hand, has
  1759. 107
  1760. John Micklethwait and Adrian Wooldridge, The Witch Doctors: Making Sense of the Management
  1761. Gurus (New York: Times Books, 1996), p. 209.
  1762. 108
  1763. Waddell and Bodek, p. 169.
  1764. no pretense of being the "property" of shareholders, and its management has no pretense
  1765. of representing shareholders. Because of the prevailing capital structure in Japan,
  1766. corporations like Toyota, generally, function as unabashedly self-governed entities that
  1767. deal with the banks as their main source of outside finance. The Japanese corporation
  1768. approaches, if not perfectly, the ideal of a stakeholder cooperative.
  1769. To the extent that companies like Toyota have problems, it comes from the distorting
  1770. effects on their structure resulting from the requirements of existing in a larger capitalist
  1771. system. That is, profit-maximization pressure from creditors, and excessive size and
  1772. hierarchy resulting from a state capitalist system that subsidizes corporate size. But
  1773. Toyota is, at the very least, an example of the kind of "liberal capitalist" firm we mention
  1774. in Chapter Fifteen, with high degrees of worker equity and worker self-management.
  1775. And at best, it allows us to extrapolate what things would be like if the Toyota system
  1776. functioned in a decentralized economy with free credit. As we will see in Chapter
  1777. Fourteen, H. Thomas Johnson argues that Toyota's lean production system, stripped of its
  1778. present distortions which result from the global corporate system, can serve as the basis
  1779. for sustainable local production. The Toyota system, applied to a local network of small
  1780. cooperative manufacturers like that in Emilia-Romagna, organized around local supply
  1781. chains rather than a continent-sized just-in-time system of "warehouses on wheels" (or
  1782. container ships), will have found its true purpose.
  1783. Blogger Richard Posner once argued that Lawrence Summers should not be
  1784. accountable to the faculty for his conduct as President of Harvard University. The reason,
  1785. he said:
  1786. They [the faculty] should not be the owners. The economic literature on worker
  1787. cooperatives identifies decisive objections to that form of organization that are fully
  1788. applicable to university governance. The workers have a shorter horizon than the institution.
  1789. Their interest is in getting as much from the institution as they can before they retire; what
  1790. happens afterwards has no direct effect on them unless their pensions are dependent on the
  1791. institution’s continued prosperity. That consideration aside (it has no application to most
  1792. professors' pensions), their incentive is to play a short-run game, to the disadvantage of the
  1793. institution--and for the further reason that while the faculty as a group might be able to
  1794. destroy the institution and if so hurt themselves, an individual professor who slacks off or
  1795. otherwise acts against the best interests of the institution is unlikely to have much effect on
  1796. the institution.109
  1797. Given the material so far in this section, Posner's bizarro-world description of
  1798. workers' short time horizons sounds like a clinically accurate description of corporate
  1799. management--but with the word "workers" substituted for "management." If anything, a
  1800. trained chicken would probably have a longer time-horizon than the average corporation's
  1801. senior management.
  1802. 109
  1803. Richard Posner, "Summers' Resignation and Organization Theory," The Becker-Posner Blog, February
  1804. 26, 2006 <http://www.becker-posner-blog.com/archives/2006/02/summers_resigna_1.html>.
  1805. The short time-horizons involved in hierarchy mean that making correct decisions
  1806. from the long-term perspective will result in someone else taking credit. On the other
  1807. hand, living off of seed corn to inflate short-term returns (at the cost of long-term
  1808. disaster) may pay off spectacularly, by enabling a careerist to outrun the consequences of
  1809. his bad decisions.110
  1810. At the plant level, this means neglecting necessary maintenance and upgrades to
  1811. inflate short-term earnings. The manager who does this can be sure that he will get a
  1812. bump up the career ladder for the immediate returns of his short-sighted policy, and the
  1813. career of a successor will be ruined instead of his own when the bills come due.111
  1814. Indeed, corporations' internal policies are often designed to facilitate such strategies.
  1815. Top management deliberately avoids any long-term tracking of the consequences of
  1816. individual decisions because it would threaten them with accountability.112
  1817. The overall effect is pressure on managers to "hit desired numbers... by squeezing the
  1818. resources under one's control..." Deferring capital expenditures, including maintenance
  1819. as well as new investment in improving the production process--referred to as "starving"
  1820. or "milking" a plant.113 Jackall quoted an upper-middle manager from the chemical
  1821. subdivision in a corporate case study:
  1822. We're judged on the short-term because everybody changes their jobs so frequently. As
  1823. long as we have a system where I'm told that I am not going to be in a job for the long term,
  1824. you're going to have this pressure. And you're not tracked from one job to the next, so you
  1825. can milk your present situation and never have it pinned on you in the future.... If a piece of
  1826. fairly large capital equipment needs to be replaced--well almost anything can be fixed and
  1827. you can just keep patching things up, just putting absolutely no money at all into the
  1828. business. Or you can just make an edict that will cut supplies by 25 percent, [things like]
  1829. pumps, motors, tools, and so on.... My favorite thing are not to replace my stores inventory
  1830. and that shows up as direct profit on your balance sheet; not replace people who retire, and
  1831. stretch everybody else out.... In the chemical business, another way to do it is to let waste
  1832. accumulate, shutting off any capital expenditures and anything that is an expense. And you
  1833. know what happens when you do that? The guy who comes into that mess is the one who
  1834. gets blamed, not the guy who milked it."114
  1835. Jackall comments:
  1836. Some managers become very adept at milking businesses and showing a consistent
  1837. record of high returns. They move from one job to another in a company, always upward,
  1838. 110
  1839. Jackall, Moral Mazes, pp. 86, 90-91..
  1840. Ibid., p. 87.
  1841. 112
  1842. Ibid., p. 88.
  1843. 113
  1844. Ibid., p. 91.
  1845. 114
  1846. Ibid., pp. 91-92.
  1847. 111
  1848. rarely staying more than two years in any post. They may leave behind them deteriorating
  1849. plants and unsafe working conditions..., but they know that if they move quickly enough, the
  1850. blame will fall on others....
  1851. In fact, the manager who "takes the money and runs" is usually not penalized but
  1852. rewarded and indeed given a license to move on to bigger mistakes.115
  1853. In one case, a manager in the chemical division Jackall studied was notorious for
  1854. having "milked and milked thoroughly every plant he ever supervised." When challenged
  1855. in a meeting for this practice, by a vice president who was his superior, he responded:
  1856. "...[H]ow can you sit there and say that to me? How in the hell do you think you got to
  1857. where you are...?"116
  1858. Jackall adds that milking is more prevalent among policymakers at corporate
  1859. headquarters than at the individual plant level, because the former are more insulated
  1860. from the consequences when things go bad:
  1861. Of course, the closer one is in the hierarchy to a business being milked, the greater the
  1862. potential danger of being caught in a catastrophe and the more sure one has to be that one
  1863. gets out in time. For this reason, managers feel that most milking, though not all, is done by
  1864. those at the top of the hierarchy who are well removed and insulated from a local situation.117
  1865. Jackall also gives a specific example of milking leading to a catastrophe. A large
  1866. coking plant in the same chemical subdivision was under pressure from the CEO to defer
  1867. "unnecessary" capital expenditures, in order to use the subdivision as a cash cow to
  1868. finance new investments. As a result, a decaying battery was patched up for four years in
  1869. lieu of the needed replacement. When it finally collapsed, the consequences to the
  1870. company were disastrous (including breach of contract with a steel producer and costly
  1871. pollution lawsuits)--total costs running from $100-150 million, compared to $6 million
  1872. for simply replacing the battery.118
  1873. The CEO's interference, and its consequences, remind me of an anecdote from
  1874. Russia's Great Patriotic War with the Nazis. The political officer of an artillery unit
  1875. forbade the commander to withdraw a short distance, despite the commander's frantic
  1876. attempts to explain that the apparent "retreat" was necessary to get proper range on the
  1877. main road along which a German column was moving. (Another, more facetious
  1878. anecdote claims that the Egyptians lost the 1967 war by literally adhering to the advice of
  1879. Soviet military manuals: "Retreat into the heartland and wait for the first snowfall.")
  1880. Another author gives a less dramatic example, in which pennywise pound-foolish cost
  1881. cutting policies severely degraded the customer service capability of a privatized utility:
  1882. 115
  1883. Ibid., p. 94.
  1884. Ibid., p. 96.
  1885. 117
  1886. Ibid., p. 93.
  1887. 118
  1888. Ibid., pp. 81-82.
  1889. 116
  1890. Management attempted to "sell" the new structure to the staff by claiming that its sole
  1891. purpose was to improve standards of service for the customer. However, the fact that
  1892. management was perceived as wishing to introduce the Beta structure "on the cheap"
  1893. (minimizing on staff training and keeping staffing levels low, pressing on with inadequate
  1894. systems because of the expense involved in correcting them quickly and so on) undermined
  1895. the claim that change was primarily intended to improve service.... This was of enormous
  1896. significance for workers who dealt constantly and directly with the customer. Management
  1897. was forcing them to provide an unsatisfactory service....119
  1898. Of course, management engages in asset-stripping, or starving or milking an
  1899. operation, not just because of pressure from outside. It also does so, as we remarked
  1900. above, because the funding of the organization's productive resources comes at the
  1901. expense of management self-dealing.
  1902. It's amusing that Deming knockoffs like TQM and Six Sigma have been such popular
  1903. fads in the corporate world, from the '90s on. Despite all their lip-service, the typical
  1904. management approach to "solving" any problem is the direct opposite of the substantive
  1905. ideas of McGregor, Drucker and Deming.
  1906. Douglas McGregor, for example, blamed "management's methods of organization and
  1907. control" for any lack of worker motivation:
  1908. Another fallacy is often revealed in management attempts to control human behavior.
  1909. When we fail to achieve the results we desire, we tend to seek the cause everywhere but
  1910. where it usually lies: in our choice of inappropriate methods of control. The engineer does
  1911. not blame water for flowing downhill rather than up.... However, when people respond to
  1912. managerial decisions in undesired ways, the normal response is to blame them. It is their
  1913. stupidity, or their uncooperativeness, or their laziness which is seized on as the explanation
  1914. of what happened, not management's failure to select appropriate means of control.120
  1915. As we will see below, Fish! Philsophy is the ultimate outgrowth of this tendency. Rather
  1916. than attempt to provide positive incentives in any way, in order to elicit the desired
  1917. behavior, Fish! attempts to manipulate the worker into liking whatever management
  1918. wants to give.
  1919. Both Peter Drucker and W. Edwards Deming opposed attempts to solve problems and
  1920. reduce costs through sloganeering. They rejected the "behavioral" approach to solving
  1921. problems (see Appendix 8A, "Blaming Workers for the Results of Mismanagement"),
  1922. and saw genuine solutions as possible only by means of structural changes in the
  1923. production process. Deming, for instance, wrote:
  1924. 119
  1925. Julia O'Connell Davidson, "The Sources and Limits of Resistance in a Privatized Utility," in J. Jermier
  1926. and D. Knights, editors, Resistance and Power in Organizations (London: Routledge, 1994), p. 85.
  1927. 120
  1928. Douglas McGregor, The Human Side of Enterprise (New York, London, Toronto: McGraw Hill Book
  1929. Company, Inc., 1960), pp. 10, 48.
  1930. Eliminate targets, slogans, exhortations, posters, for the work force that urge them to increase
  1931. productivity. "Your work is your self-portrait. Would you sign it?" No--not when you give
  1932. me defective canvas to work with, canvas not suited to the job, brushes worn out, so that I
  1933. can not call it my work. Posters and slogans like these never helped anyone to do a better
  1934. job....
  1935. "Do it right the first time." A lofty ring it has. But how could a man make it right the
  1936. first time when the incoming material is off-gauge, off-color, or otherwise defective, or if his
  1937. machine is not in good order, or the measuring instruments not trustworthy? This is just
  1938. another meaningless slogan, a cousin of zero defects.
  1939. "Getting better together." Production workers have told me that this slogan makes them
  1940. furious. Together! What is that when no one will listen to our problems and suggestions?121
  1941. Drucker, likewise, dismissed "management by drives," with pennywise/pound-foolish
  1942. "economies" that degrade long-term productivity. To focus on individual effort rather
  1943. than process only produces, at best, a short-term bump in productivity that quickly
  1944. evaporates.122
  1945. Robert Jackall observed that most managers take a fairly cynical view of management
  1946. theory fads like reengineering and quality. They serve more as a legitimizing ideology
  1947. than as a serious guide to action--much as did appeals to the old libertarian and
  1948. humanistic symbolism of the historic socialist movement, for the authoritarian Party
  1949. apparatus in the Soviet oligarchy.
  1950. Of course, senior managers do not themselves necessarily believe in such programs. In
  1951. one seminar I attended, the senior manager in charge startled a room of juniors by saying:
  1952. Fellows, why aren't any of you asking about the total lack of correspondence between
  1953. what we're preaching here and the way we run our company?
  1954. But such outspokenness is rare. Managers privately characterize such programs as the
  1955. "CEO's incantations over the assembled multitude," as "elaborate rituals with no practical
  1956. effect," or as "waving a magic wand to make things wonderful again.".... Publicly, of course,
  1957. managers on the way up adopt with great enthusiasm those programs that have caught their
  1958. bosses' fancy, participate in or run them very effectively, and then quietly drop them when
  1959. the time is right.123
  1960. Management is also prone to a sort of magical thinking, thinking that to put
  1961. something into writing has some corresponding effect on reality. As Paul Goodman said,
  1962. 121
  1963. Deming, Out of the Crisis, pp. 65-66.
  1964. Peter F. Drucker, The Practice of Management (New York: Harper & Brothers Publishers, 1954), pp.
  1965. 127-128.
  1966. 123
  1967. Jackall, Moral Mazes, pp. 142-143.
  1968. 122
  1969. It is to will to be in control, without adjusting to the realities.... In this fantasy they
  1970. employ a rhetoric of astounding dissociation between idea and reality.... For example, they
  1971. claim that they are depolluting streams, but they allot no money; ...the depressed area of
  1972. Appalachia has been reclaimed, but the method is an old highway bill under another name;
  1973. poor people will run their own programs, but any administrator is fired if he tries to let them;
  1974. ...this seems to be just lying, but to my ear it is nearer to magic thinking.124
  1975. This has been true of management thinking since it first emerged as a separate
  1976. discipline, as Yehouda Shenhav describes it:
  1977. The systematizers' emphasis on formalization through systems was promoted as rational, but
  1978. it was a particular type of rationality, labeled by economist Friedrich Hayek as "constructive
  1979. rationality" or "plan rationality"....
  1980. Formalization was also to include the company rules. Some suggested the company rules
  1981. and policy should be posted in industrial bulletins.... For example..., "The rate of pay is a
  1982. personal matter between the individual employee and employer, and must not become the
  1983. business of other persons." It was suggested that each bulletin "established harmony at
  1984. once". Furthermore, "everyone seemed to be infused with a desire to make a good record"
  1985. and with "loyalty".125
  1986. Some of this, no doubt, is plausible deniability or "C.Y.A." If a written policy is in
  1987. place, management can blame systemic problems on subordinates who disregard policy.
  1988. For example, consider Tyson's response when an undercover PETA activist working in a
  1989. Tyson facility filmed inhumane slaughter of poultry:
  1990. [Tyson] said the man had signed a document confirming he had completed the company's
  1991. animal-welfare training "and was responsible for ensuring that no birds remained alive. His
  1992. job gave him the responsibility to process any live birds, stop the line or sound an alarm if
  1993. there was a problem."....
  1994. Responding to the company's statement, PETA said its investigator had been "taught to
  1995. rip the animals' heads off by a plant supervisor, for when there are too many who miss the
  1996. neck slicer."126
  1997. Auschwitz and Treblinka no doubt had a "written policy" against killing Jews.
  1998. Corporate hierarchies, as Robert Jackall describes them, have a strong tendency to
  1999. "push down detail." One purpose is to avoid responsibility for failure. By setting general
  2000. objectives and leaving subordinates responsible for the details, those at the top retain the
  2001. 124
  2002. Paul Goodman, Like a Conquered Province, p. 339.
  2003. Yehouda Shenhav, Manufacturing Rationality: The Engineering Foundations of the Managerial
  2004. Revolution (New York and Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1999), pp. 87-88. Quotes are from American
  2005. Machinist, Oct. 22, 1914.
  2006. 126
  2007. "Tyson Foods Under Fine for Inhumane Slaughter of Poultry," Agribusiness Examiner, June 6, 2005
  2008. #408 <http://www.organicconsumers.org/OFGU/tyson060605.cfm>.
  2009. 125
  2010. right to shift the blame for failure--even if the general objective assigned was unrealistic
  2011. given the resources senior management was willing to allocate.
  2012. ...[P]ushing down details relieves superiors of the burden of too much knowledge,
  2013. paticularly guilty knowledge.
  2014. ...[B]ecause they are unfamiliar with--indeed distance themselves from--entangling
  2015. details, corporate higher echelons tend to expect successful results without messy
  2016. complications. This is central to executives' well-known aversion to bad news and to the
  2017. resulting tendency to kill the messenger who bears the news.127
  2018. But as much of the "management mentality" results from the need for plausible
  2019. deniability, a great deal also results as well from the psychotically distorted and isolated
  2020. world in which management operates, thanks to the informational filtering mechanisms
  2021. described by R.A. Wilson and Kenneth Boulding in Chapter Five. Management is under
  2022. the illusion that its policies are actually carried into effect, at the bottom end of the
  2023. hierarchical filtering mechanism, in a fashion even remotely resembling their intentions.
  2024. For example, here's how Peters and Waterman describe the "manager's mentality":
  2025. We behave as if the proclamation of policy and its execution were synonymous. "But I made
  2026. quality our number one goal years ago," goes the lament.... [The] president's subordinate
  2027. clarified the message, "Of course, he's for quality. That is, he's never said, 'I don't care about
  2028. quality.' It's just that he's for everything. He says, 'I'm for quality,' twice a year and he acts,
  2029. 'I'm for shipping product,' twice a day."128
  2030. Management may pay lip service to quality, but any subordinate who reduces short-term
  2031. income for the sake of a long-term improvement in quality is taking his life in his own
  2032. hands.
  2033. Cut off almost completely from an understanding of the production process and the
  2034. prerequisites for real efficiency, management puts production workers in a double bind by
  2035. officially demanding particular results while systematically stripping them of all the
  2036. resources needed to achieve those results. Or in the words of a Dilbert character, "Boss
  2037. World: where the laws of time, space, and logic do not apply." In boss-think, when one
  2038. says something in a mission statement or in "educational" handouts, the language has a
  2039. magical effect on reality: a verbal formula "makes it so" without the expenditure of any
  2040. money (and especially without the diversion of resources from management
  2041. featherbedding to production).
  2042. The information filtering mechanisms described by Wilson and Boulding don't just
  2043. work automatically. They're actively enforced from above. It's true, as Wilson said, that
  2044. people tend to self-censor based on what they think those in authority want to hear. But
  2045. 127
  2046. Jackall, Moral Mazes, pp. 20-21.
  2047. Thomas J. Peters and Robert H. Waterman, In Search of Excellence: Lessons from America's Best-Run
  2048. Companies (New York: Warner Books, 1982), p. 73.
  2049. 128
  2050. those at the top of the pyramid also suppress negative feedback on the effects of their
  2051. policies. According to Joyce Rothschild and Terance Miethe, whistleblowers usually
  2052. start out attempting to work within the system, naively expecting that management wants
  2053. to improve the system and will welcome their feedback in good faith. Only when
  2054. management responds by trying to destroy them do they air their message to the outside
  2055. world, in self-defense.
  2056. ...[W]e find that whistleblowers start out expecting a constructive or at least modest
  2057. organizational response to their disclosures. In our interviews, whistleblowers told us time
  2058. and again that they started out believing that because they were respected and valued
  2059. employees, their information presented to "higher-ups" would be taken seriously and would
  2060. be the catalyst for the constructive organizational change they sought. As a result, few were
  2061. prepared for what was about to happen to them....
  2062. Often, what we find is that once employees reveal they possess and might use
  2063. information that challenges management's judgement, the full resources of the organization
  2064. will be brought to bear against them.... In cases we studied, upon learning that an individual
  2065. had a concern and information that could be used against them, management immediately
  2066. fired the individual, or if that was not possible, then they set up the process by which they
  2067. could be later fired, by abruptly downgrading their job performances.
  2068. If their claims of "incompetence" could not be sustained, then we found that managers
  2069. sometimes resorted to a tactic that we had not anticipated: they would endeavour to get the
  2070. whistleblower labelled "crazy". Towards this end, management would direct the
  2071. whistleblower to see an agency or company psychologist and would inform the psychologist
  2072. that the person was being sent because they appeared to be "out of their mind" or a "paranoid
  2073. schizophrenic"....
  2074. It is important to understand that as soon as management first hears of the concerns and
  2075. information of the whistleblower, they often act immediately to downgrade the individual's
  2076. job performance and begin explicitly to build a case for firing the individual. In other words,
  2077. management reprisals begin as soon as management becomes aware that the individual might
  2078. become a whistleblower.129
  2079. More generally, the same corporations that slavishly professed Kwality as the
  2080. management fad du jour in the '90s blatantly ignored one of Deming's central principles:
  2081. "Drive out fear." Fear systematically shapes and distorts the information that moves up
  2082. the hierarchy, while reaffirming the official picture of reality is a test of loyalty. For
  2083. example, a survey at a number of companies attempted to discover what issues employees
  2084. considered "undiscussable," and found the number one answer was "management
  2085. practices."130 Thus, management suppresses exactly the kind feedback from subordinates
  2086. that is most needed to assess the effectiveness of company policy.
  2087. 129
  2088. Joyce Rothschild and Terance D. Miethe, "Whistleblowing as Resistance in Modern Work
  2089. Organizations: The Politics of Revealing Organizational Deception and Abuse," in A. Baum and J.E.
  2090. Singer, eds., Advances in Environmental Psychology (Hillsdale, N.J.: Earlbaum, 1980), pp. 264-266.
  2091. 130
  2092. Cloke and Goldsmith, The End of Management, p. 49.
  2093. Most employees are reluctant to discuss morale-reducing behaviors openly with their
  2094. managers, primarily because of management's superior power, causing employee morale to
  2095. decline even further due to a lack of open, honest, authentic, timely communication or
  2096. genuine efforts at resolution. In nearly all organizational cultures, employees speak more
  2097. freely with each other than they do with managers, and monitor their communications with
  2098. managers to make sure they do not risk termination....
  2099. Many common managerial behaviors silence employees and reduce morale: giving
  2100. orders, micromanaging, reproving, repeating the company line, listening bureaucratically,
  2101. ducking difficult issues, hiding behind superiors, refusing responsibility for mistakes, passing
  2102. the buck, and punishing those perceived as troublemakers. If we added up the damage
  2103. caused and opportunities wasted by these personally and organizationally destructive
  2104. behaviors, the figure would be astronomical and far outweigh the salaries of the managers
  2105. who engaged in them.131
  2106. At Jackall's "Covenant" corporation, managers stated the importance of, variously,
  2107. "aligning oneself with the dominant ideology of the moment," or "bowing to whichever
  2108. god currently holds sway."
  2109. ...[T]he belief of insiders in abstract goals is not a prerequisite for personal success;
  2110. belief in and subordination to individuals who articulate organizational goals is. One must,
  2111. however, be able to act, at a moment's notice, as if official reality is the only reality.... The
  2112. knowledgeable practitioners of corporate politics, whether patrons or leaders of cliques and
  2113. networks, value nothing more highly than at least the appearance of unanimity of opinion
  2114. among their clients and allies, especially during times of turmoil.132
  2115. The ideology of "team play" is a powerful weapon for enforcing groupthink, by
  2116. suppressing dissent. As one of Jackall's mid-level managers at Covenant said,
  2117. Someone who is talking about team play is out to squash dissent. It's the most effective
  2118. way to tell people who have [different?] perspectives to shut up.... [Bosses] say they don't
  2119. want a yes man, but, in fact, most bosses don't want to hear the truth. And this is particularly
  2120. true if it disagrees with what they want to do.133
  2121. The information filters in hierarchies are not only effective in suppressing information
  2122. that contradicts the official picture of reality. They are also quite adept, if not at making
  2123. policies that deal effectively with reality, then at least at constantly tweaking the official
  2124. ideology to explain why reality didn't work as predicted:
  2125. What's interesting and confusing at the same time is the way guys around here will switch
  2126. explanations of things from day to day and not even notice.... Like they explain the current
  2127. stanation of our stock one day by referring to the Falkland Islands war; the next day, it's the
  2128. 131
  2129. Ibid., p. 55.
  2130. Jackall, Moral Mazes, pp. 52-53.
  2131. 133
  2132. Ibid., pp. 54-55.
  2133. 132
  2134. bearish stock market; the next, it's the Fed's interest policy; the next, the unsettled political
  2135. conditions. And so on and so on. And they don't remember the explanation they gave a
  2136. month ago. They end up going around believing in fairy tales that might have no relationship
  2137. to reality at all.134
  2138. For the most part those at or near the top of a hierarchy will suffer few moral qualms
  2139. in adapting to its requirements for suppressing the truth. As Gordon Tullock said, the
  2140. greater the extent to which advancement in a hierarchy demands the sacrifice of ordinary
  2141. personal morality, the greater the advantage the amoral climber will have over his more
  2142. scrupulous colleagues; as a result, the hierarchy selects against morality and that
  2143. undesirable trait has been effectively weeded out at the top.135
  2144. Given all these phenomena, it's not surprising that career advancement within the
  2145. corporate hierarchy is generally perceived to have little to do with genuine achievement.
  2146. Robert Jackall writes:
  2147. Managers rarely speak of objective criteria for achieving success because once certain
  2148. crucial points in one's career are passed, success and failure seem to have little to do with
  2149. one's accomplishments.
  2150. The corporate hierarchy relies, instead, on credentialling for the presumption of
  2151. competence, and on a culture of obedience and careerism to guarantee the correct attitude
  2152. toward the values of the hierarchy.136
  2153. Profits and other kinds of results matter, but managers see no necessary connections between
  2154. performance and reward. Although meritocratic ideologies are constantly invoked in the
  2155. corporate world to explain or justify promotions, demotions, or other organizational changes,
  2156. such rationales are always viewed by managers with a measure of skepticism....
  2157. ....Merit pay systems, for instance, are widely considered to be used simply as
  2158. sophisticated, highly rational legitimations for what is in practice a complicated political
  2159. patronage system....
  2160. Work comes to be seen as separated from reward. One might surmise that bonus
  2161. systems, tied to specific accomplishments, could mend such a breach at least for those
  2162. included in such plans.
  2163. But there is often a built-in inequity between the classes of management which are
  2164. included or excluded from such programs. At Covenant Corporation, "even during the...
  2165. rocky red-ink years [of the 1981 recession]..., generous bonuses were regularly passed out
  2166. to the chosen few."137
  2167. 134
  2168. Ibid., pp. 146-147.
  2169. Gordon Tullock, The Politics of Bureaucracy (Washington, D.C.: Public Affairs Press, 1965), p. 22.
  2170. 136
  2171. Jackall, Moral Mazes, p. 41.
  2172. 137
  2173. Ibid., pp. 62-64. It's interesting, by the way, how the corporate culture views the motivation of senior
  2174. management compared to that of production workers. It is considered perfectly normal and legitimate for
  2175. 135
  2176. As a result, there is an understandable fear of showing initiative or sticking one's neck
  2177. out. Those at the top either seek plausible deniability, or seek "buy-in" from subordinates
  2178. in order to implicate as many people as possible in the shared blame if a decision leads to
  2179. bad results. Those at the bottom, on the other hand, keep their heads down and avoid
  2180. making commitments, and wait for those at the top to take the initiative. One manager at
  2181. Covenant said:
  2182. People try to cover themselves. They avoid putting things clearly in writing. They try to
  2183. make group decisions so that responsibility is not always clearly defined....
  2184. [These tendencies are] rooted in the pervasive social uncertainty of the organization...,
  2185. [i.e.] management's sense of organizational contingency, of authoritarian capriciousness, and
  2186. of the lack of firm connections between risk and reward.138
  2187. Management's approach to corporate governance was ably summed up by Preston
  2188. Glidden, a frequent commenter at my blog with a fifteen year background in corporate
  2189. quality control and quality assurance:
  2190. Modern management's goal is to squeeze the last drop of blood out of a company's
  2191. quarterly numbers, while fooling customers and investors about the actual long-term health
  2192. of the company. If it kills the company in the long term, so be it. The golden parachute
  2193. awaits senior management, and employees pay the price.139
  2194. C. The Authoritarian Workplace: Increased Hierarchy and Surveillance.
  2195. The elites who run our state capitalist economy made a strategic decision, in the
  2196. 1970s, to cap real wages and transfer all productivity increases into reinvestment,
  2197. dividends, or CEO salaries. So while real wages have remained stagnant for thirty years,
  2198. the wealth of the top few percent of the population has exploded astronomically. The
  2199. percentage of wealth owned by the top 1%, which as of the mid-70s had held steady at
  2200. around 25% for decades, is now close to 40%. To impose this policy on society,
  2201. obviously, required increasing authoritarianism in all aspects of social life. I quote at
  2202. length from my account, in Studies in Mutualist Political Economy, of the considerations
  2203. CEOs to require multimillion salaries and bonus packages to overcome their natural tendency to screw over
  2204. the shareholder, whereas production workers are expected to enthusiastically carry progressively heavier
  2205. workloads with stagnant pay with gimmicks like "values statements" and "Fish! Philosophy" as their only
  2206. motivation.
  2207. 138
  2208. Ibid., p. 79.
  2209. 139
  2210. Preston Glidden comment under Kevin Carson, "Liberation Management, or Management by Stress?"
  2211. Mutualist Blog: Free Market Anticapitalism, August 28, 2006
  2212. <http://mutualist.blogspot.com/2006/08/liberation-management-or-management-by.html>.
  2213. that went into that elite policy140:
  2214. The American corporate elite reacted in the 1970s to the combination of fiscal,
  2215. accumulation and legitimation crises by adopting a neoliberal agenda of curtailing
  2216. consumption and subsidizing new accumulation. Along with these new policies, it adopted
  2217. the forms of political control necessary to force them on a recalcitrant population.
  2218. Until the late 1960s, the elite perspective was governed by the New Deal social compact.
  2219. The corporate state would buy stability and popular acquiescence in imperialist exploitation
  2220. abroad by guaranteeing a level of prosperity and security to the middle class. In return for
  2221. higher wages, unions would enforce management control of the workplace. As Richard K.
  2222. Moore put it, prosperity would guarantee public passivity. But starting in the Vietnam era,
  2223. the elite's thinking underwent a profound change.
  2224. They concluded from the 1960s experience that the social contract had failed. Besides
  2225. unprecedented levels of activism in the civil rights and antiwar movements, and the general
  2226. turn toward radicalism among youth, the citizenry at large also became less manageable.
  2227. There was a proliferation of activist organizations, alternative media, welfare-rights
  2228. organizations, community activism, etc.
  2229. Elite intellectuals like Samuel P. Huntington lamented the drastic decrease in the level of
  2230. trust of government and other leading institutions among the general public. In The Crisis of
  2231. Democracy, written by Huntington and others as an inaugural paper for the Trilateral
  2232. Institution (an excellent barometer of elite thinking), the authors argued that the system was
  2233. collapsing from demand overload, because of an excess of democracy...
  2234. For Huntington, America's role in maintaining the global state capitalist system depended
  2235. on a domestic system of power; this system of power, variously referred to in this work as
  2236. corporate liberalism, Cold War liberalism, and the welfare-warfare state, assumed a general
  2237. public willingness to stay out of government affairs. For the first two decades or so after
  2238. WWII, the U.S. had functioned as "the hegemonic power in a system of world order." And
  2239. this was only possible because of a domestic structure of political authority in which the
  2240. country "was governed by the president acting with the support and cooperation of key
  2241. individuals and groups in the Executive office, the federal bureaucracy, Congress, and the
  2242. more important businesses, banks, law firms, foundations, and media, which constitute the
  2243. private establishment."
  2244. America's position as defender of global capitalism required that its government have the
  2245. ability "to mobilize its citizens for the achievement of social and political goals and to
  2246. impose discipline and sacrifice upon its citizens in order to achieve these goals." Most
  2247. importantly, this ability required that democracy be largely nominal, and that citizens be
  2248. willing to leave major substantive decisions about the nature of American society to qualified
  2249. authorities. It required, in other words, "some measure of apathy and non-involvement on the
  2250. part of some individuals and groups."
  2251. Unfortunately, these requirements were being gravely undermined by "a breakdown of
  2252. 140
  2253. Kevin Carson, Studies in Mutualist Political Economy
  2254. traditional means of social control, a delegitimation of political and other means of
  2255. authority, and an overload of demands on government, exceeding its capacity to respond."
  2256. ....The task of traditional state capitalist elites, in the face of this crisis of democracy,
  2257. was to restore that "measure of apathy and noninvolvement," and thus to render the system
  2258. once again "governable."
  2259. In response to the antiwar protests and race riots, LBJ and Nixon began to create an
  2260. institutional framework for coordination of police state policy at the highest levels, to make
  2261. sure that any such disorder in the future could be dealt with differently. This process
  2262. culminated in Department of Defense Civil Disturbance Plan 55-2, Garden Plot, which
  2263. involved domestic surveillance by the military, contingency plans for military cooperation
  2264. with local police in suppressing disorder in all fifty states, plans for mass preventive
  2265. detention, and joint exercises of police and the regular military....
  2266. The New Deal social compact with organized labor was reassessed in the light of new
  2267. events. The country was swept by a wave of wildcat strikes in the early 1970s, in coal
  2268. mining, auto manufacturing, and the post office. These disruptions indicated that the
  2269. business unions could no longer keep their rank and file under control, and that the Fordist
  2270. system was no longer serving its purpose of maintaining social control in the workplace.
  2271. At the same time, the business press was flooded with articles on the impending "capital
  2272. shortage," and calls for shifting resources from consumption to capital accumulation, by
  2273. radically scaling back the welfare state and hamstringing organized labor. This shift was
  2274. reflected in traditionally corporate liberal think tanks like Brookings and the CED, which
  2275. both produced studies acknowledging the need to impose limits on consumption in the
  2276. interest of accumulation; for example, the Brookings Institution's 1976 study Setting
  2277. National Priorities: The Next Ten Years.
  2278. Business journals predicted frankly that a cap on real wages would be hard to force on
  2279. the public in the existing political environment. For example, an article in the October 12,
  2280. 1974 issue of Business Week warned that
  2281. Some people will obviously have to do with less.... [I]ndeed, cities and states, the home
  2282. mortgage market, small business and the consumer will all get less than they want.... [I]t will
  2283. be a hard pill for many Americans to swallow--the idea of doing with less so that big
  2284. business can have more.... Nothing that this nation, or any other nation has done in modern
  2285. history compares in difficulty with the selling job that must now be done to make people
  2286. accept the new reality.
  2287. This only heightened the imperative to curb the excess of democracy and make the state
  2288. less vulnerable to popular pressure.
  2289. Corporations embraced the full range of union-busting possibilities in Taft-Hartley,
  2290. risking only token fines from the NLRB. They drastically increased management resources
  2291. devoted to workplace surveillance and control, a necessity because of discontent from
  2292. stagnant wages and mounting workloads (aka increased "productivity").
  2293. ....Wages as a percentage of value added have declined drastically since the 1970s, and
  2294. real wages have been virtually flat. Virtually all increases in labor productivity have been
  2295. channeled into profit and investment [not to mention management salaries], rather than
  2296. wages. The new Cold War military buildup, from the late '70s on, still further transferred
  2297. public resources to industry.
  2298. A series of events like the fall of Saigon, the nonaligned movement, and the New
  2299. International Economic Order were taken as signs that the transnational corporate empire
  2300. was losing control. The national security community saw America's "system of world order"
  2301. coming under increasing pressure from national liberation movements. An excellent example
  2302. of foreign policy elites' view of the near future is the work of RAND analyst Guy Pauker,
  2303. who wrote in 1977 of a "possible world order crisis in the 1980s."
  2304. Reagan's escalating intervention in Central America was a partial response to this
  2305. perception. But more importantly, the collapse of the USSR ended all external restraints on
  2306. the global system designed during WWII, and deprived internal resistance to that system of
  2307. the Soviet Union's patronage. In the aftermath of this snatching of total victory from the jaws
  2308. of defeat, the Uruguay Round of GATT ended all barriers to TNCs buying up entire
  2309. economies, locked the west into monopoly control of modern technology, and created a
  2310. world government on behalf of global corporations....
  2311. In the meantime the U.S. was moving toward radical polarization of income. The general
  2312. effect of the neoliberal reaction was to blur the lines between imperial core and periphery:
  2313. the comprador bourgeoisie, living in heavily fortified luxury sectors of Third World cities,
  2314. coexisted with the gated communities of America as elements of the core; at the same time,
  2315. something resembling a Third World society has arisen in parts of what was traditionally the
  2316. First World. The inner city and the depopulated countryside, the seats of urban and rural
  2317. squalor, respectively, were subject to increasing surveillance and brutality under the guise of
  2318. the War on Drugs. "Most of the world has been turned into a periphery; the imperial core
  2319. has been boiled down to the capitalist elite themselves...."
  2320. As policy elites attempted to transform the country into a two-tier society, a kinder and
  2321. gentler version of the Third World pattern, the threat of public discontent forced the
  2322. government to greater and greater levels of authoritarianism.
  2323. The most obvious means of social control, in a discontented society, is a strong, semimilitarized police force. Most of the periphery has been managed by such means for
  2324. centuries. This was obvious to elite planners in the West, was adopted as policy, and has now
  2325. been largely implemented....
  2326. So that the beefed-up police force could maintain control in conditions of mass unrest,
  2327. elite planners also realized that much of the Bill of Rights would need to be neutralized....
  2328. The rights-neutralization project has been largely implemented, as exemplified by armed
  2329. midnight raids, outrageous search-and-seizure practices, overly broad conspiracy laws,
  2330. wholesale invasion of privacy, massive incarceration, and the rise of prison slave labor.
  2331. "The Rubicon," Moore concludes, "has been crossed--the techniques of oppression long
  2332. common in the empire's periphery are being imported to the core."
  2333. With the help of the Drug War, and assorted Wars on Gangs, Terrorism, etc., the
  2334. apparatus of repression continued to grow....
  2335. This authoritarianism, in response to perceived disgruntlement over the clampdown,
  2336. has been reflected to an especially strong degree in the workplace. This was the theme of
  2337. David M. Gordon's Fat and Mean: The Corporate Squeezing of Working Americans and
  2338. the Myth of Managerial Downsizing. As the title suggests, management downsizing in
  2339. the 80s and 90s has largely been a myth. In fact, the proportion of the labor force in
  2340. supervisory positions has grown, along with the proportion of total compensation going to
  2341. management salaries. Hierarchy, authoritarianism, and internal surveillance have
  2342. increased, largely from their perceived necessity for dealing with a workforce disgruntled
  2343. over stagnant wages and rising work loads.
  2344. As Gordon observes, real hourly take home pay for production and non-supervisory
  2345. workers fell over ten percent from the mid-70s to the mid-90s, reaching roughly the same
  2346. levels as in the late '60s--this, despite the fact that per capita GDP in constant dollars was
  2347. 53% higher.141 Average non-supervisory wages skyrocketed, in 1994 dollars, from $6.40
  2348. in 1948 to $10.50 in 1972. Then from 1972 to 1992 they fell to $9.40.142 During the
  2349. 1980s, while productivity growth averaged 12% a year, real wages actually fell by 0.6% a
  2350. year.143
  2351. Meanwhile, despite the conventional view to the contrary, the proportion of managers
  2352. and supervisors actually grew during the 1990s.144 Executive, administrative and
  2353. managerial employees in private, nonfarm employment rose from 12.6% to 13.2% of the
  2354. labor force. Managers made up 26.6% of nonfarm job growth from 1991-95.145 In 1995,
  2355. the Wall Street Journal debunked the myth of management downsizing: the "corporate
  2356. giants," associated with the most dramatic stories of managerial layoffs, had "more
  2357. managers per 100 employees today than... in 1993."146 What's more, the percentage of
  2358. national income going to management was increased drastically. In 1973 40.4% of
  2359. national income went to production workers, and 16.2% to supervisory employees. In
  2360. 1993 the figures were 34.5% and 24.1%, respectively.147 In other words, over twenty
  2361. years management salaries rose from 28.6% to 41.1% of total employee compensation.
  2362. The difference would have been enough to increase the hourly pay of production workers
  2363. by almost 25%.
  2364. Cross-national comparisons are just as informative. Compared to 13% of the U.S.
  2365. nonfarm private sector workforce, management was a much smaller proportion in Europe
  2366. and Japan. On the European continent, the percentage ranged from 2.6% in Sweden to
  2367. 6.8% in Norway; in Japan, it was 4.2%.
  2368. 141
  2369. David M. Gordon, Fat and Mean: The Myth of Management Downsizing, p. 4.
  2370. Ibid., p. 19.
  2371. 143
  2372. Ibid., pp. 68-69.
  2373. 144
  2374. Ibid., p. 5.
  2375. 145
  2376. Ibid., pp. 52-54.
  2377. 146
  2378. Alex Markels, "Restructuring Alters Middle-Management Role But Leaves It Robust," Wall Street
  2379. Journal, Sept. 25, 1995, in Ibid., p. 58.
  2380. 147
  2381. Gordon, Fat and Mean, p. 82.
  2382. 142
  2383. And bear in mind, as Seymour Melman points out, that the proportional increase in
  2384. management was almost entirely for the sake of control, not efficiency:
  2385. Within firms, managerial activity and costs proliferate independently of their effects on
  2386. production. Studies of the relation between the costs of managing and the volume of
  2387. industrial production have found either a negative correlation or the absence of any
  2388. significant linkage at all. From 1977 to 1980, for example, the value of goods and services
  2389. produced in the United States rose 7.9 percent, while employment of blue-collar and whitecollar workers grew 2 and 12 percent respectively. The jobs of the blue-collar people were
  2390. clearly linked to output; the tasks of the much-enlarged white-collar group were mainly
  2391. undertaken for control rather than production.... Evidently the extension of such control has
  2392. been given priority, even over profitability, in the mores of management....
  2393. ...[T]he largest part of the growth [in administrative employees] has been in the functions
  2394. that enhance control, not in those that increase production.148
  2395. Gordon's thesis is that the two trends, "the wage squeeze" and "the bureaucratic
  2396. burden," are directly connected:
  2397. In one direction, stagnant or falling wages create the need for intensive management
  2398. supervision of frontline employees. If workers do not share in the fruits of the enterprise, if
  2399. they are not provided a promise of job security and steady wage growth, what incentive do
  2400. they have to work as hard as their bosses would like? So the corporations need to monitor
  2401. the workers' effort and be able to threaten credibly to punish them if they do not perform.
  2402. The corporations must wield the Stick. Eventually the stick requires millions of Stickwielders.
  2403. In the other direction, once top-heavy corporate bureaucracies emerge, they acquire their
  2404. own, virtually ineluctable expansionary dynamic. They push for more numbers in their ranks
  2405. and higher salaries for their members. Where does the money come from? ...One of the
  2406. most obvious targets is frontline workers' compensation. The more powerful the corporate
  2407. bureaucracy becomes, and the weaker the pressure with which employees can counter, the
  2408. greater the downward pressure on production workers' wages.149
  2409. As the cross-national statistics on the management burden above suggest, the facts
  2410. tend to bear out this correlation. Gordon observes that high bureaucratic burdens tend to
  2411. be associated with "conflictual" labor-management relations:
  2412. ...the wage squeeze and the bureaucratic burden in the United States are integrally connected;
  2413. each contributes directly to the other. They comprise two essential components of a system
  2414. of production and management in the United States that builds on conflict and hierarchy,
  2415. insecurity and coercion. "The United States has the highest amount of conflict between
  2416. business and labor of any democratic nation," concludes MIT labor expert Thomas Cochan....
  2417. 148
  2418. 149
  2419. Seymour Melman, Profits Without Production (New York: Alfred A. Knopf, 1985), pp. 70-71.
  2420. Gordon, Fat and Mean., pp. 5-6.
  2421. In short, "fat" and "mean" go together like the proverbial horse and carriage. In our
  2422. economy, it would appear, you can't have one without the other. The international data
  2423. certainly feed such a suspicion, since the United States has recently featured both the slowest
  2424. real wage growth and the top-heaviest corporate bureaucracies among the leading advanced
  2425. economies.150
  2426. When workers have a high degree of job security and expectations of steady wage
  2427. increases corresponding to productivity growth, they can be trusted "to coordinate many
  2428. of their own activities in production, relieving their corporate owners of the need for
  2429. intensive and continuous monitoring and supervision."
  2430. With a coercive approach, by contrast, a much more fundamental conflict between
  2431. owners and workers is likely to persist over workers' labor effort. Corporations are naturally
  2432. interested in their employees working as hard as possible. In the absence of strong wage
  2433. benefits and employment security, however, what provides the worker with the incntive to
  2434. work anywhere nearly as intensively as the corporation would prefer? Indeed, why should he
  2435. or she work very hard at all?....
  2436. The solution to such motivational problems in the absence of strong wage incentives and
  2437. well-established job security in general, is a combination of intensive supervision of
  2438. employees and the threat of job dismissal. If the worker can't be trusted to work diligently
  2439. when left to him- or herself, the firm needs to watch the worker closely, monitoring nearly
  2440. every move, alert to those unwanted moments of shirking, evading, and lollygagging that
  2441. undermine firm performance....
  2442. And so in the absence of the carrot, conflictual systems are likely to display legions of
  2443. stick-wielders as one of their central features, armies of supervisors and managers saddled
  2444. with the principal direct or indirect responsibility for ensuring that production and
  2445. nonsupervisory workers don't shirk on the job....
  2446. Can't trust your workers when left to their own devices? Peer over their shoulders.
  2447. Watch behind their backs. Record their movements. Monitor them. Supervise them. Boss
  2448. them. Above all else, don't leave them alone....
  2449. Increasingly intensive supervision grew more and more necessary after the early 1970s
  2450. because, far from sharing productivity dividends with employees as a way of spurring their
  2451. effort, corporations on balance have been driving down wages and taking away other
  2452. employee benefits and protections as well.151
  2453. The important thing to note about all these trends described by Gordon is that
  2454. management doesn't just have a zero-sum relationship with workers. It has, to almost the
  2455. same extent, a zero-sum relationship with stockholders. Gordon cites a meeting of
  2456. twenty-one experts on corporate management in the late '70s; all of them agreed or agreed
  2457. strongly with the statement that "In many cases control and power are more important to
  2458. 150
  2459. 151
  2460. Ibid., p. 62.
  2461. Ibid., pp. 65-66, 68.
  2462. managers than profits or productivity." The management hierarchy possesses a great deal
  2463. of autonomy, and tends to promote its own expansion at the expense of both wages and
  2464. profits. Management prestige is reflected in the number of subordinates in one's petty
  2465. bureaucratic empire, much like the feudal magnates whose prosperity was judged by the
  2466. number of liveried retainers. Management tends to engage in featherbedding at the
  2467. expense both of worker compensation and returns on equity.152
  2468. Note, especially, some indicators in Gordon's account--you might miss them if you
  2469. don't look closely--of corporate management's veto-power over organized capital. For
  2470. one thing, note that the policy elites of the early '70s did not see high management
  2471. compensation as competing for the resources needed for capital investment. Although the
  2472. compensation of hourly workers declined drastically from 1973 to 1993, according to
  2473. Gordon's figures above, they were more than offset by the rise in management salaries. In
  2474. fact, the total compensation of production workers and management together rose from
  2475. 56.6% to 58.6% of national income during that period. So if there were a zero-sum
  2476. relationship between employee compensation and investment, then the workplace policies
  2477. of the past thirty years have increased, not reduced, total employee compensation at the
  2478. expense of funds available for investment. It's just that a lot more of it goes to useless
  2479. eaters. On the other hand, once the decision was made to disipline production workers,
  2480. the increased levels of hierachy and supervision required made capital even more
  2481. dependent on management and more vulnerable to management self-dealing and other
  2482. agency problems.
  2483. Work monitoring has become much more intensive. For example, consider this new,
  2484. intrusive system for monitoring warehouse workers in Britain:
  2485. Workers in warehouses across Britain are being "electronically tagged" by being
  2486. asked to wear small computers to cut costs and increase the efficient delivery of goods
  2487. and food to supermarkets, a report revealed yesterday.
  2488. New US satellite- and radio-based computer technology is turning some workplaces
  2489. into "battery farms" and creating conditions similar to "prison surveillance", according to
  2490. a report from Michael Blakemore, professor of geography at Durham University.
  2491. The technology, introduced six months ago, is spreading rapidly, with up to 10,000
  2492. employees using it to supply household names such as Tesco, Sainsbury's, Asda, Boots
  2493. and Marks & Spencer....
  2494. Under the system workers are asked to wear computers on their wrists, arms and
  2495. fingers, and in some cases to put on a vest containing a computer which instructs them
  2496. where to go to collect goods from warehouse shelves.
  2497. The system also allows supermarkets direct access to the individual's computer so
  2498. orders can be beamed from the store. The computer can also check on whether workers
  2499. 152
  2500. Ibid., pp. 75-78.
  2501. are taking unauthorised breaks and work out the shortest time a worker needs to
  2502. complete a job....
  2503. Martin Dodge, a researcher at the centre for advanced spatial analysis at University
  2504. College London, said: "These devices mark the total 'disappearance of disappearance'
  2505. where the employee is unable to do anything without the machine knowing or
  2506. monitoring."....
  2507. In a typical example of Official Happy Talk, management's assessment of the results of
  2508. their own policy is (predicatably) positively glowing:
  2509. But the companies say the system makes the delivery of food more efficient, cuts out
  2510. waste, reduces theft and can reorder goods more quickly.
  2511. One firm, Peacock Retail Group, claims workers like the system. The company,
  2512. which has a modern centre in Nantgarw, south Wales, where employees have 28
  2513. wearable computers and six mounted on trucks, says the system has a positive impact on
  2514. team morale. "Everybody likes the wearables because they are comfortable and easy to
  2515. use. The result is the team finds it easier to do the job," it says on the company website.
  2516. A spokeswoman for Tesco last night insisted that the company was not using the
  2517. technology to monitor the staff and said it was making employees' work easier and
  2518. reducing the need for paper.
  2519. Happy workers, united in joy, under the far-seeing guidance of Dear Leader! As you
  2520. might expect, those doing the actual work in that authoritarian environment see things a
  2521. bit differently:
  2522. But at the GMB's annual conference in Newcastle yesterday one of the union's
  2523. national officers, Paul Campbell, said: "We are having reports of people walking out of
  2524. jobs after a few days' work, in some cases just a few hours. They are all saying that they
  2525. don't like the job because they have no input. They just followed a computer's
  2526. instructions."153
  2527. Peter Skott and Frederick Guy suggest that the introduction of automation and
  2528. monitoring capability, more generally, is responsible for the stagnation of wages in
  2529. service industry over the past generation. "Power-biased technological change," by
  2530. enabling management to monitor unskilled and semi-skilled labor more closely, has
  2531. reduced the bargaining power of labor--thus simultaneously increasing work intensity
  2532. and exerting a downward pressure on wages.154 With such technology, management
  2533. can control the pace of work in service industry in the same way that an automated
  2534. production line does in manufacturing. Of course, as we will see in the next chapter,
  2535. 153
  2536. David Hencke, "Firms Tag Workers to Improve Efficiency," The Guardian, June 7, 2005
  2537. <http://www.guardian.co.uk/supermarkets/story/0,12784,1500851,00.html>.
  2538. 154
  2539. Peter Skott and Frederick Guy, "A Model of Power-Biased Technological Change," September 14, 2006
  2540. <http://www.people.umass.edu/pskott/SkottGuyFinalVersion13Sept2006.pdf>.
  2541. such a strategy has built-in limits. While management may be able to monitor
  2542. selected aspects of effort expenditure, there are always some aspects of the workplace
  2543. environment that are not amenable to effective monitoring. As Oliver Williamson
  2544. showed, workers are apt to maintain adequate levels of effort in areas of job
  2545. performance that are monitored, while shifting to perfunctory compliance (or worse)
  2546. in areas that are not effectively monitored. And if workers become disgruntled
  2547. enough over the pace of work, they can probably find ways to impose astronomical
  2548. cost increases in the areas not amenable to monitoring, with little or no chance of
  2549. getting caught. I can testify from personal experience, in an increasingly downsized
  2550. and sped-up hospital, that this is no mere theoretical possibilities. The costs from
  2551. employee disgruntlement--deliberate waste and destruction, and supplies given away
  2552. free to patients rather than being charged to their accounts--probably exceed by far
  2553. what would have been the cost of hiring adequate levels of staff and raising their pay
  2554. to acceptable levels.
  2555. The need for monitoring and surveillance probably has a lot to do with the failure
  2556. of telecommuting to live up to the early hype. Chris Dillow, of Stumbling and
  2557. Mumbling blog, writes on the culture of "presenteeism":
  2558. [A]n often overlooked feature of the new economy... [is] that many workers now have more
  2559. and better capital equipment at home than they do at work.
  2560. This destroys the traditional reason for going out to work; in industrial societies we had
  2561. to go to factories because that was where the machinery was.
  2562. With this reason no longer applying for many of us, one would expect to have seen an
  2563. explosion in the numbers of people working from home. After all, there are enormous costs
  2564. to having workplaces separate from our homes; commuting and rent to name but two.
  2565. However, teleworking is still rare....
  2566. ...I suspect the main obstacle to the growth of teleworking is not technology but power.
  2567. Offices (and maybe factories too) exist not because they are technically efficient but because
  2568. they provide easy ways for the boss class to supervise and control workers.
  2569. In the course of his argument, he cited Stephen Marglin's excellent article "What Do
  2570. Bosses Do?"155 which argued that the advantage of the factory lay less in its superior
  2571. technical efficiencies over home production, than in its superior efficiency at securing
  2572. effort and extracting surplus value from the laborer. As evidence that the surprising
  2573. failure of telecommuting to take off reflected similar interests, he cites the fact
  2574. that teleworkers contain disproportionate numbers of self-employed. In the US, the selfemployed account for two-thirds of all teleworkers even though they are only 7 per cent of
  2575. 155
  2576. Steven A. Marglin. "What Do Bosses Do? The Origins and Functions of Hierarchy in Capitalist
  2577. Production--Part I" Review of Radical Political Economics 6:2 (Summer 1974).
  2578. all workers. In the UK, the self-employed are 11 per cent of the labour force but 43 per cent
  2579. of teleworkers. Is it really plausible that this is purely the result of different technologial
  2580. requirements between the self-employed and the employed? Or is it not evidence that
  2581. working for others means subordination, which means working in offices even when it is not
  2582. technically necessary to do so?156
  2583. Claire Wolfe attributed the conspicuous absence of telecommuting, at least on the
  2584. scale predicted fifteen years ago, to similar power motivations:
  2585. Although computer-based “knowledge work” hasn't enabled millions of us to leave the
  2586. corporate world and work at home (as, again, it was supposed to), that's more a problem of
  2587. corporate power psychology than of technology. Our bosses fear to “let” us work
  2588. permanently at home; after all, we might take 20-minute coffee breaks, instead of 10!157
  2589. Personality profiling and testing are also becoming much more intrusive.
  2590. Increasingly paranoid about employee disgruntlement (probably in part because of
  2591. their own bad consciences), management tries ever more obsessively to root out any
  2592. evidence their workers may be concealing non-Stepford Wife opinions behind a
  2593. facade of obedience.
  2594. For example, Barbara Ehrenreich mentions an interview with Wal-Mart at a job
  2595. fair, of which the centerpiece was a four-page "opinion survey" ("no right or wrong
  2596. answers," according to the rather dubious assurance of the interviewer). Among other
  2597. things, it asks "whether management is to blame if things go wrong...."158 Well, I
  2598. guess that depends on whether the guy who cuts you off at the knees is responsible for
  2599. you falling down.
  2600. What these tests tell employers about potential employees is hard to imagine, since
  2601. the "right" answers should be obvious to anyone who has ever encountered the principle
  2602. of hierarchy and domination. Do I work well with others? You bet, but never to the
  2603. point where I would hesitate to inform on them for the slightest infraction. Am I capable
  2604. of independent decision making? Oh yes, but I know better than to let this capacity
  2605. interfere with a slavish obedience to others. At The Maids, a housecleaning service, I am
  2606. given something called the "Accutrac personality test," which warns at the beginning that
  2607. "Accutrac has multiple measures which detect attempts to distort or 'psych out' the
  2608. questionnaire." Naturally, I "never" find it hard "to stop moods of self-pity," nor do I
  2609. imagine that others are talking about me behind my back or believe that "management
  2610. and employees will always be in conflict because they have totally different sets of
  2611. goals." The real function of these tests, I decide, is to convey information not to the
  2612. employer but to the potential employee, and the information being conveyed is always:
  2613. 156
  2614. Chris Dillow, "Capitalism and Presenteeism," Stumbling and Mumbling blog, June 21, 2005
  2615. <http://stumblingandmumbling.typepad.com/stumbling_and_mumbling/2005/06/capitalism_and_.html>
  2616. 157
  2617. Claire Wolfe, "Dark Satanic Cubicles," Loompanics 1995 Catalog <http://www.loompanics.com/cgilocal/SoftCart.exe/Articles/darksatanic.html> (Loompanics site now defunct; link no longer active).
  2618. 158
  2619. Barbara Ehrenreich, Nickel and Dimed: On (Not) Getting By in America (New York: Henry Holt and
  2620. Co., 2001), p. 58.
  2621. You will have no secrets from us. We don't just want your muscles and that part of your
  2622. brain that is directly connected to them, we want your innermost self.159
  2623. Now, my approach to preemployment personality tests has been zero tolerance vis-avis the obvious "crimes"--drug use and theft--but to leave a little wriggle room
  2624. elsewhere, just so it doesn't look like I'm faking out the test. When presenting yourself as
  2625. a potential employee, you can never be too much of a suck-up. Take the test proposition
  2626. that "rules have to be followed to the letter at all times": I had agreed to this only
  2627. "strongly" rather than "very strongly" or "totally" and now Roberta wants to know
  2628. why.160
  2629. ...Job searches take their toll, even in the case of totally honest applicants, and I am
  2630. feeling particularly damaged. The personality tests, for example: the truth is that I don't
  2631. much care if my fellow workers are getting high on the parking lot or even lifting the
  2632. occasional retail item, and I certainly wouldn't snitch if I did. Nor do I believe that
  2633. management rules by divine right or the undiluted force of superior knowledge, as the
  2634. "surveys" demand you acknowledge.... Equally draining is the effort to look both perky
  2635. and compliant at the same time, for half an hour at a stretch, because while you need to
  2636. evince "initiative," you don't want to come across as someone who might initiate
  2637. something like a union organizing drive.161
  2638. D. Authoritarianism: Contract Feudalism.
  2639. The term "contract feudalism" was coined by Elizabeth Anderson in a post at
  2640. Left2Right blog:
  2641. ...Under feudalism, wealthy landlords employed hundreds of retainers, servants, and
  2642. tenants who depended on them for subsistence. The price of dependence was servility: the
  2643. duty to obey any arbitrary whim, however humiliating, called out as an order to them by their
  2644. lord. Commerce and manufactures liberated individuals from such abject servility, by
  2645. enabling people to live off sales to thousands of customers instead of one master. It enabled
  2646. large numbers of people to enjoy personal independence for the first time....
  2647. Of course, matters were different for wage laborers than for independent shopkeepers
  2648. and craftsmen. Wage laborers did have to obey an arbitrary master on the factory floor.
  2649. But their subjection to this authority was mitigated, and their personal dependence
  2650. from the employer secured, by
  2651. the separation of work from the home. However arbitrary and abusive the boss may have
  2652. been on the factory floor, when work was over the workers could at least escape his tyranny
  2653. (unless they lived in a factory town, where one's boss was also one's landlord and regulator
  2654. 159
  2655. Ibid., p. 59.
  2656. Ibid., p. 124.
  2657. 161
  2658. Ibid., p. 127.
  2659. 160
  2660. of their lives through their leases). Again, in the early phase of industrialization, this was
  2661. small comfort, given that nearly every waking hour was spent at work. But as workers
  2662. gained the right to a shortened workday--due to legislation as well as economic growth--the
  2663. separation of work from home made a big difference to workers' liberty from their employers'
  2664. wills.
  2665. Nevertheless, to the extent that this liberty is secured by competition for workers and
  2666. convention alone, rather than by legal right, it is vulnerable to invasion.162
  2667. And sure enough, as the bargaining power of labor has decreased over the past thirty
  2668. years (and to repeat what we said above, that's the result of a very deliberate policy
  2669. decision by the corporate state), the separation of work from the home has undergone
  2670. steady erosion. A growing portion of the workforce finds itself subject to management
  2671. whims even away from the job, and personal time subject to intrusion from work, in a
  2672. way quite reminiscent of the feudal vassal's 24/7 subjection to his master's whims. Hence
  2673. Anderson's term "contract feudalism": the contractual alienation of personal
  2674. independence by propertyless people, whose lack of bargaining power renders them
  2675. vulnerable, in return for subsistence, and the corresponding conversion of the propertied
  2676. classes' ownership into dominion over people.163
  2677. Contract feudalism covers a wide range of events that have been in the news lately.
  2678. One is described by Anderson in her blog post. According to the New York Times,164
  2679. Howard Weyers, president of Michigan-based Weyco, in early 2005 forbade his workers
  2680. to smoke--"not just at work but anywhere else." The policy, taken in response to the rising
  2681. cost of health coverage, requires workers to submit to nicotine tests.
  2682. Guardsmark, a security company, forbids its workers to socialize with each other off
  2683. the job--a policy upheld by an NLRB ruling. The Washington Post's Harold Meyerson
  2684. compares the employer's power to issue such arbitrary commands to the power of--you
  2685. guessed it--a feudal lord:
  2686. There's a word for the kind of employer-employee relationship that the NLRB has just
  2687. sanctioned. It's "feudal." The brave new world that emerges from this ruling looks a lot like
  2688. the bad old world where earls and dukes had the power to control the lives of their serfs -not just when the serfs were out tilling the fields but when they retired in the evening to the
  2689. comfort of their hovels. But then the Bill of Rights in America has never reached very far
  2690. into the workplace. And now, the strictures on workers' rights within the workplace are being
  2691. extended without.165
  2692. 162
  2693. Elizabeth Anderson, "Adventures in Contract Feudalism," Left2Right blog, Feb. 10, 2005
  2694. <http://left2right.typepad.com/main/2005/02/adventures_in_c.html>.
  2695. 163
  2696. Elizabeth Anderson, "How Not to Complain About Taxes (II): Against Natural Property Rights,"
  2697. Left2Right blog, Jan. 20, 2005 <http://left2right.typepad.com/main/2005/01/why_i_reject_na.html>.
  2698. 164
  2699. NYT, Feb. 8, 2005 <http://www.nytimes.com/2005/02/08/business/08smoking.html>.
  2700. 165
  2701. Harold Meyerson, "Big Brother on and Off the Job," Washington Post, Aug. 10, 2005
  2702. <http://www.washingtonpost.com/wp-dyn/content/article/2005/08/09/AR2005080901162.html>.
  2703. An especially alarming trend is "Doocing," i.e. the firing of bloggers for public
  2704. comments written on their own time: for example, Joe Gordon, editor of the
  2705. Woolamaloo Gazette166 blog, who was fired from Waterstone's (a UK chain bookstore
  2706. roughly comparable to B&N) when it came to his bosses' attention that he'd made the
  2707. occasional venting post (quite mild, from my perspective) after a particularly bad day at
  2708. work.167 Gordon, who arranged book promotions and was friendly with a number of
  2709. prominent science fiction authors (including post-Trot/libertarian/cyberpunk fusionist
  2710. Ken MacLeod, via whose blog I originally heard of the story),168 brought Waterstone's
  2711. business worth many times his salary; and although he was ostensibly fired for bringing
  2712. them into "disrepute," Waterstone's clueless and ham-fisted management have themselves
  2713. done more to that end by firing Gordon than a thousand employee blogs could possibly
  2714. have done.
  2715. Blogger B.K Marcus, in discussing his experiences with libertarian writers who later
  2716. attempt to remove their writings from the Web, hints that some of them might be
  2717. motivated by the fear of what a prospective employer might stumble upon.169 The danger
  2718. is a very real one. As someone who was hunting a job myself only three years ago, and as
  2719. a prolific writer with a large body of online material on radical political and economic
  2720. themes, I well remember my paranoia that the HR Nazis might Google my name during
  2721. the application process.
  2722. Workers are increasingly required to be on-call for extended periods, or reachable at
  2723. all times, during what used to be called "their own time." Consider, for example, the
  2724. "open availability" policy of some Wal-Mart stores, which regional management also
  2725. tried to make official company policy:
  2726. Wal-Mart officials in Cross Lanes told employees on Tuesday they have to start working
  2727. practically any shift, any day they’re asked, even if they’ve built up years of seniority and
  2728. can’t arrange child care....
  2729. “We have many people with set schedules who aren’t here when we need them for our
  2730. customers,” said John Knuckles, a manager at the store, which is located in the Nitro
  2731. Marketplace shopping center and employs more than 400.
  2732. “It is to take care of the customers, that’s the only reason,” he said.
  2733. Workers who have had regular shifts at the store for years now have to commit to being
  2734. available for any shift from 7 a.m. to 11 p.m., seven days a week. If they can’t make the
  2735. 166
  2736. <http://www.woolamaloo.org.uk/>
  2737. Patrick Barkham, "Blogger sacked for sounding off," The Guardian, Jan. 12, 2005
  2738. <http://www.guardian.co.uk/online/weblogs/story/0,14024,1388466,00.html> (link defunct).
  2739. 168
  2740. Ken Macleod, "The Case of the Blogging Bookseller," The Early Days of a Better Nation, Jan. 12. 2005
  2741. <http://kenmacleod.blogspot.com/2005_01_01_kenmacleod_archive.html#110551826393727206>.
  2742. 169
  2743. B.K. Marcus, "The Memory Hole," lowercase liberty blog, Jan. 19, 2005
  2744. <http://www.bkmarcus.com/blog/2005/01/memory-hole.html>.
  2745. 167
  2746. commitment by the end of this week, they’ll be fired.
  2747. “It shouldn’t cause any problem, if they [store employees] are concerned about their
  2748. customers,” Knuckles said.
  2749. Several single mothers working at the store have no choice now but to quit, said one
  2750. employee, who would not give her name for fear of retribution.
  2751. “My day care closes at 6 and my baby sitter can’t work past 5,” said the employee, a
  2752. mother of two who has been a cashier for more than three years. Neither of the services is
  2753. available over the weekends, she added. “I have to be terminated; I don’t know what I’ll do.”
  2754. “Wal-Mart is supposed to be a family-oriented company, but kids don’t matter,” the
  2755. worker said.
  2756. Along with the “open-availability” policy, the store is requiring all floor employees to
  2757. learn how to run cash registers, several employees said. They suspect this is an attempt to
  2758. brace for the departure of many of the employees who now work as cashiers.
  2759. When announcing the new policies, store managers said they expected to lose about 60
  2760. people, according to another employee who asked not to be named.
  2761. “They said sales were down so much, they had to make a change,” the worker said. “The
  2762. past year they’ve really been nitpicking” longer-term employees, who are paid more.
  2763. “A lot of people were mad and there were women crying — it’s just terrible,” said the
  2764. worker, who has been at the store six years. “I’ve put up with a few things, but this has got to
  2765. be the worst thing I’ve seen them do.”
  2766. Other Wal-Mart stores have open-availability rules, but it does not appear to be required
  2767. of each store by company headquarters. Managers at Wal-Marts in South Charleston and
  2768. Ripley refused to comment, but one employee at the store in Spencer, also speaking on
  2769. condition of anonymity, said there was no such policy in place there.170
  2770. Although the Wal-Mart stores involved in the story beat a hasty retreat in the face of
  2771. intense public criticism, there is some indication similar policies have since been
  2772. implemented on a store-wide level.
  2773. ....Sally Wright, 67, an $11-an-hour greeter at the Wal-Mart in Ponca City, Okla., said she
  2774. quit in August after 22 years with the company when managers pressed her to make herself
  2775. available to work any time, day or night.
  2776. ....The company says it gives employees three weeks’ notice of their schedules and takes
  2777. their preferences into account, but that description differs from those of many workers
  2778. interviewed. Workers said that their preferences were often ignored and that they were often
  2779. 170
  2780. Joe Morris, "Wal-Mart institutes availability requirement," The Charleston Gazette, June 15, 2005, in
  2781. Wake Up Wal-Mart blog <http://www.wakeupwalmart.com/news/20050615-cg.html>.
  2782. given only a few days’ notice of scheduling changes....
  2783. But some workplace experts point to the downside of the policies. Susan J. Lambert, a
  2784. professor of social sciences at the University of Chicago who has written several research
  2785. papers on retail workers, called it a burden for employees to cope with constant schedule
  2786. changes.
  2787. “You have to set up child care for every day just in case you have to work,” she said,
  2788. “and this makes it hard to establish routines like reading to your kids at night or having
  2789. dinner together as a family.”...
  2790. A big area of discrepancy between what Wal-Mart says and what the workers say is
  2791. whether the company has a policy of “open availability,” requiring employees to make
  2792. themselves available around the clock. Ms. Clark, the Wal-Mart spokeswoman, said the
  2793. company had no such a policy, adding, “Our main goal is to match the ratio of associates to
  2794. customers shopping in our stores resulting in better customer service hour by hour.” WalMart says it pays higher wages to night-shift workers.
  2795. But in March, workers from a Wal-Mart in Nitro, W.Va., held a small protest rally in the
  2796. center of town after Wal-Mart managers demanded 24-hour availability and cut the hours of
  2797. workers who balked. And workers from other stores around the country said in interviews
  2798. that similar demands had been made on them.
  2799. Houston Turcott, the former overnight stocking manager at the Wal-Mart in Yakima,
  2800. Wash., said that managers had told workers, “Either they had full, open availability so we
  2801. can schedule them when we would like or we would cut their hours.”
  2802. Tracie Sandin, who worked in the Yakima store’s over-the-counter drug department until
  2803. last February, said, “They said, if you don’t have open availability, you’re put on the bottom
  2804. of the list for hours.”171
  2805. The use of "concern about the customers" to justify such policies is especially telling.
  2806. A major aspect of contract feudalism is the extension of the "professionalist" ideology
  2807. into even unskilled service jobs. The minimum wage housekeeper, retail or restaurant
  2808. worker is now expected to have the same sense of "calling," of dedication to customer
  2809. service, and of career as a source of identity, as members of the traditional professions-but without the pay or the autonomy.
  2810. E. Authoritarianism: The Hegemony of "Professionalism."
  2811. The professionalist ideology is closely linked to the related phenomenon, described
  2812. above, of contract feudalism.
  2813. 171
  2814. Steven Greenhouse and Michael Barbaro, "Wal-Mart to Add Wage Caps and Part-Timers," The New
  2815. York Times, October 2, 2006 <http://www.nytimes.com/2006/10/02/business/02walmart.html>.
  2816. Consider, again, our discussion above of the level of single-minded dedication to
  2817. "customer service," the 24/7 availability, and the identification with one's job as a career,
  2818. required even from unskilled service workers. The only area of the job market where such
  2819. things were expected, before the 1970s, was the white collar salariat of "professional"
  2820. employees. (I'm leaving out anomalies like Southern sharecroppers and workers in
  2821. company towns, where employees were considered to be "property" of the employer to a
  2822. large extent; but by the middle of the 20th century, that was looked on as a relic of the
  2823. past, not the wave of the future--as it's becoming now).
  2824. For a good fictional example, take a look at Darren Stevens on the TV series
  2825. Bewitched. He was a white collar "professional" in the advertising industry. Most of the
  2826. comic situations on the show hinged on frequent "visits" to Darren's house by his boss,
  2827. Larry Tate, a partner in the advertising firm, and Darren's need to entertain clients at
  2828. home. Darren was constantly having to explain his unusual lifestyle to Larry, who
  2829. obviously felt entitled to an explanation. And that intrusion in itself, remember, wasn't
  2830. meant to be viewed as especially comical by the audience; it was just a set-up for all the
  2831. wacky comic situations resulting from Samantha's witchcraft. The background itself was
  2832. just based on the common understanding of what life was like for the "organization man."
  2833. And as a comedy of "how the other half lives," it was especially humorous to the
  2834. blue-collar manufacturing worker just because it was so unlike his own way of life.
  2835. Imagine a master machinist in the IAM tolerating constant drop-in visits from a foreman,
  2836. who felt entitled to demand explanations for odd happenings in the machinist's home! At
  2837. the time, such intrusion of the "career" into one's homelife was associated entirely with
  2838. white collar work. As Orwell's character George Bowling put it in Coming Up for Air,
  2839. There's a lot of rot talked about the sufferings of the working class. I'm not so sorry for the
  2840. proles myself.... The prole suffers physically, but he's a free man when he isn't working. But
  2841. in every one of those little stucco boxes there's some poor bastard who's NEVER free except
  2842. when he's fast asleep and dreaming that he's got the boss down the bottom of a well and is
  2843. bunging lumps of coal at him.
  2844. But except for a very small and shrinking remnant of unionized manufacturing
  2845. workers, "we're all organization men now." The ethos of white collar "professionalism"
  2846. has contaminated a major part of wage labor.
  2847. The concept of professionalism has achieved an unprecedented hegemony in society
  2848. at large. For a very large part of the population, one's identity as "a professional" is the
  2849. main source of reference. People commonly, in situations where they are required to sum
  2850. themselves up, simply identify themselves as professional. The "professional" selfdesignation appears in the same social contexts as "citizen" did fifty years ago. In the
  2851. 1950s, it was common for someone to refer to himself, in situations completely removed
  2852. from politics or government, as "just an ordinary citizen," or the like. Today, for many in
  2853. the white collar middle class, it's "a professional." Professionalism has acquired the same
  2854. ideological significance once held by civic culture and citizenship. In either case, the
  2855. individual was defined in terms of some particular authority relation in which he existed.
  2856. Letters to advice columnists commonly begin with some phrase like this: "Dear Abby,
  2857. my husband and I are both professionals in our 40s...." The implied subtext, of course, is
  2858. "...so obviously this isn't something we caused by our own stupidity," or "...so this is a
  2859. legitimate problem, unlike those of most of the beer-swilling yahoos who read your
  2860. column."
  2861. The concept of the profession has also largely supplanted that of the skilled trade in
  2862. the occupational realm. The adjective "professional" is used almost exclusively to
  2863. describe work or behavior that once would have been described as "businesslike," or
  2864. characterized by a sense of craftsmanship. "Professional" and "unprofessional" are used
  2865. as words of praise and blame, respectively, in occupations that were never regarded as
  2866. professions back when the term had any meaning. People in virtually all white collar or
  2867. service jobs, regardless of the level of training associated with them, are expected to
  2868. display "professionalism" in their work attitudes and dress.
  2869. The ideology of "professionalism" has spread like a cancer and contaminated most
  2870. occupations. Originally, the culture of the professions grew out of the skilled trades. A
  2871. master of arts, for example, was analogous to a master of any other trade, with bachelors
  2872. and undergraduates corresponding to journeymen and apprentices; a university was a
  2873. place where one apprenticed to a master scholar. As we saw in Chapter Four, in the
  2874. nineteenth century even the professions of medicine and law were generally perpetuated
  2875. by some sort of informal apprenticeship system, rather than standardized education and
  2876. occupational licensing. But I'd gladly compromise on the original five professions-letters, medicine, law, holy orders, and arms--if we could only reclaim the concept of the
  2877. skilled trade for everything else.
  2878. So why has professionalism so successfully colonized the entire realm of work? Who
  2879. benefits from promoting it as an ideology? What functions does it serve?
  2880. The fundamental purpose of professionalism, like that of any other ideology, is to get
  2881. people's minds right--in this case, workers.
  2882. Professionalism fosters a house-slave mentality by getting large categories of workers
  2883. to identify with management (Good ole Massa knows we're really like him, white on the
  2884. inside--we're not like those shiftless old field slaves), setting white collar against blue
  2885. collar workers, and enabling management to rule through a divide-and-conquer strategy.
  2886. There's a saying that a dishonest man is the easiest target for a con artist. Likewise, it's a
  2887. lot easier to exploit a status-insecure snob, as long as he can be a notch or two above
  2888. someone else who's exploited worse.
  2889. Professionalism undermines the separation of work and home. Throughout the entire
  2890. service sector, increasingly, low-paid wage workers are expected to think of their job as a
  2891. calling, and of customer service as something to sacrifice "ownlife" for. In nursing, a
  2892. trade that fell under the spell of professionalism long ago, this is old news. For all of
  2893. living memory, hospital managements have cynically manipulated nurses' concern for
  2894. their patients to guilt them into working unwanted overtime. This is often done,
  2895. deliberately, in preference to hiring enough staff to avoid overtime, because it economizes
  2896. on the costs of benefits.
  2897. But the phenomenon has spread far beyond licensed nurses. As we saw in the
  2898. reference in the section above to Wal-Mart's 24/7 availability policy, the same kind of
  2899. selfless "professional" dedication is now required in the lowest levels of the two-tier
  2900. economy.
  2901. Ken Blanchard has expressed great dissatisfaction with the TGIF mentality, speaking
  2902. for many managers who resent their workers' view of the job as a means to an end, and of
  2903. their life in the outside world as the end their job serves. As Blanchard put it in his
  2904. introduction to the Fish! Philosophy book, "too many people are trading time on the job
  2905. to satisfy needs elsewhere..." Imagine that! People view going to a place where they're
  2906. treated like a disposable resource, worked like dogs, and required to take orders, as a
  2907. necessary evil, rather than looking forward to it as the central source of meaning in their
  2908. lives. Next, he'll be complaining about the people in prison who count down the days
  2909. until they get out. Come to think of it, I guess it's only a matter of time until prison
  2910. inmates join the ranks of "professionals," and are expected to volunteer for "overtime"
  2911. after they complete their sentences. After all, a good professional is willing to do
  2912. whatever it takes to avoid inconveniencing all those customers who are waiting on their
  2913. license plates or laundry.
  2914. Finally, management tries to identify "professionalism" with obedience and docility.
  2915. This means, in concrete terms, that talking back to management and fighting for one's
  2916. rights are forms of conduct unbecoming "a professional." Pressuring management to
  2917. improve working conditions, reduce hours, increase staffing or pay, and the like, are the
  2918. kinds of "low-class" behavior that proles engage in. Unions are for the Ralph Kramden
  2919. types, not for respectable wannabes like us.
  2920. In the old days, before the metastatic spread of professionalism diluted its meaning,
  2921. professions tended to maintain a collegial mentality, an internal solidarity, against the
  2922. demands of authority--much like the master craftsmen who resisted the watering down of
  2923. quality in the industrial revolution. A professional might resist unreasonable demands
  2924. from outside, like a demand to do substandard work or cut corners to compensate for
  2925. understaffing, because of professional pride. Today, outside the old-line professions,
  2926. professionalism has ceased to be a moral basis for resistance to authority, and instead
  2927. become another force for promoting obedience and identification with authority.
  2928. This aspect of professionalism gets back to the divide and conquer function I
  2929. mentioned above: "professionalism" means seeing oneself in the same social category as
  2930. management (albeit at a lower rung), and as part of the same "team." It's the vicarious
  2931. self-esteem acquired by a house slave who identifies with the owner rather than with the
  2932. field slaves. Professionalism, along with the rest of the meritocratic ideology of which it
  2933. is a part, is used to legitimize job segmentation and hierarchy within the enterprise. The
  2934. effect is to set blue and white collar workers in competition against each other, and to
  2935. coopt white collar workers into identification with management rather than labor.
  2936. In U.S. economic life, legitimation has been intimately bound up with the technocraticmeritocratic ideology.... Several related aspects of the social relations of production are
  2937. legitimized, in part, by the meritocratic ideology. To begin with, there are the overall
  2938. characteristics of work in advanced U.S. capitalism: bureaucratic organization, hierarchical
  2939. lines of authority, job fragmentation, and unequal pay. It is essential that the individual
  2940. accept and, indeed, come to see as natural, these undemocratic and unequal aspects of the
  2941. workaday world. Moreover, the staffing of these positions must appear egalitarian in process
  2942. and just in outcome, parallel to the formal principle of "equality of all before the law" in a
  2943. liberal democracy.
  2944. This legitimation of capitalism as a social system has its counterpart in the individual's
  2945. personal life. Then, just as individuals must come to accept the overall social relations of
  2946. production, so workers must respect the authority and competence of their own "supervisors"
  2947. to direct their activities, and justify their own authority... over others....
  2948. The hallmark of the meritocratic perspective is its reduction of a complex web of social
  2949. relationships in production to a few rules of technological efficiency. In this view, the
  2950. hierarchical division of labor arises from its natural superiority as a device to coordinate
  2951. collective activity and nurture expertise. To motivate the most able individuals to undertake
  2952. the necessary training and preparation for occupational roles, salaries and status must be
  2953. clearly associated with level in the work hierarchy....
  2954. This meritocratic ideology has remained a dominant theme of the mainstream of social
  2955. science since the rise of the factory system in the United States. The robustness of this
  2956. perspective... is due, in no small part, to its incorporation in major social institutions-factories, offices, government bureaus, and schools. For the technocratic justification of the
  2957. hierarchical division of labor leads smoothly to a meritocratic view of the process by which
  2958. individuals are matched to jobs. An efficient and impersonal bureaucracy, so the story goes,
  2959. assesses the individual purely in terms of his or her expected contribution to production.
  2960. And the main determinants of job fitness are seen to be those cognitive and psychomotor
  2961. capacities relevant to the worker's technical ability to do the job. The technocratic view of
  2962. production, together with the meritocratic view of hiring, provides the strongest form of
  2963. legitimation of alienated work and social stratification in capitalist society. Not only does it
  2964. strongly reinforce the notion that the hierarchical division of labor is technically necessary...,
  2965. but it also justifies the view that job assignment is objective and efficient and, therefore, just
  2966. and egalitarian....
  2967. The linking of technical skills to economic success indirectly via the educational system
  2968. strengthens... the legitimation process. First, the day-to-day contact of parents and children
  2969. with the competitive, cognitively oriented school environment, with clear connections to the
  2970. economy, buttresses, in a very immediate and concrete way, the technocratic perspective on
  2971. economic organization.... Second, by rendering the outcome (educational attainment)
  2972. dependent not only on ability but also on motivation, drive to achieve, perseverance, and
  2973. sacrifice, the status allocation mechanism acquires heightened legitimacy. Moreover, such
  2974. personal attributes are tested and developed over a long period of time, underlining the
  2975. apparent objectivity and achievement orientation of the statification system. Third, frequent
  2976. failures play an important role in gradually bringing a student's aspirations into line with his
  2977. or her probable career opportunities.172
  2978. The talking head commentariat of the corporate center (the New Deal liberal, New
  2979. Democrat, and neoconservative strands of maninstream politics are almost equally
  2980. managerialist) are decidedly meritocratic in their view of contemporary economic issues.
  2981. For all of them, the main cause for the ill fortunes of the bottom tier of the labor force
  2982. under globalization is the lack of adequate education to get with the program, and the
  2983. solution for everybody is education and more education. Stern but avuncular figures
  2984. ranging from Dr. Phil to Bill Cosby solemnly remind teenagers that the only way to
  2985. success is to "get an education." Neoconservative practitioners of "tough love" stridently
  2986. assert that the solution to all our educational ills is more "discipline," hierarchy, school
  2987. uniforms, along with a greater homework burden and the dedication of every waking hour
  2988. to drilling for the SATS or testing mandated by "No Child Left Behind." Correspondence
  2989. school commercials show grousing workers confronted by a boss who says "I used to
  2990. have a 'dead end job' just like you, until I went back to school to become a boss--and you
  2991. can too!"
  2992. This is a classic example of the fallacy of composition, as we saw Joe Bageant argue
  2993. in Chapter Four. The state capitalist system can only use so many managerial and
  2994. technical workers. The effect of expanded managerial and technical education is merely
  2995. to overproduce white collar workers, so that the educational requirements for menial
  2996. labor are inflated and those who manage to win out in the musical chairs competition for
  2997. white collar jobs wind up adopting a dog-eat-dog mentality toward those whom they beat
  2998. out.
  2999. The managerialist-meritocratic perspective also ignores several central, salient facts:
  3000. 1) in most cases the education and credentialling imposed by professionalism are far in
  3001. excess of any level that could be justified by the objective requirements of any actual
  3002. tasks to be performed; 2) the system selects for the most hierarchical and technocratic
  3003. ways of organizing production, even when the same quality of output could be achieved
  3004. by less deskilling technology, for the sake of rendering the workforce more amenable to
  3005. control; and 3) for most tasks involved in coordinating and organizing production, the
  3006. most important source of qualification is direct experience in the process, and the typical
  3007. pointy-haired boss is often clueless as to the real effect of his decisions on the production
  3008. process.
  3009. F. Motivational Propaganda as a Substitute for Real Incentives.
  3010. Ever since social science was applied to the workplace in the early 20th century, there
  3011. 172
  3012. Samuel Bowles and Herbert Gintis, Schooling in Capitalist America: Educational Reform and the
  3013. Contradictions of Economic Life (New York: Basic Books, Inc., Publishers, 1976), pp. 104-106.
  3014. has been no dearth of humanistic theories of employee relations; the Human Relations
  3015. movement and Theory Y management are the most prominent early examples.
  3016. Unfortunately, their implementation has been limited almost entirely to lip service. More
  3017. than one commentator has observed that they amount, in practice, to sugar-coated
  3018. Taylorism or Theory X management.173 Tom Peters, for example, dismissed the great
  3019. majority of corporate motivational programs, despite all the "respect for others" and
  3020. "golden rule" rhteoric, as either "lip service" or "gimmicks," intended mainly to "serve as
  3021. a smoke-screen while management continues to get away with not doing its job of real
  3022. people involvement."174
  3023. The reason isn't hard to find: it's because all such management theory fads, no matter
  3024. how humanistic and empowering their rhetoric, are implemented by bosses. And the
  3025. primary interest of management is in cementing its control of the workplace and its ability
  3026. to derive status and perks from that position of control. Real "people involvement"
  3027. wastes resources that might otherwise fund more of those perks. So the main thing
  3028. adopted from fashionable theories of worker empowerment is the jargon. The jargon of
  3029. "empowerment" is used as motivational propaganda to elicit more effort from workers
  3030. who have no real share in decisionmaking, no real control over the work process, and no
  3031. real share in the productivity gains from working more efficiently. As we said earlier, if
  3032. corporate management ever adopted Jeffersonianism as a management theory fad, they'd
  3033. pay lip service to the empowering parts, and really put into practice only the part about
  3034. screwing your slaves.
  3035. And from the start, the empowering part of humanistic theories of management was
  3036. largely superficial. As Thomas Frank said, "Whether Taylorist or humanist, theories of
  3037. management were sold as a way of defusing class conflict while keeping control of the
  3038. shop floor firmly in the hands of the owners."175 That's especially true of the fads of the
  3039. '90s: Deming, quality circles, Six Sigma, and the like. While Deming himself was a
  3040. brilliant observer of the production process, the managers who have ostensibly adopted
  3041. his ideas have in fact adopted only the rhetoric. The very workplaces that most
  3042. energetically used Kwality rhetoric were also most likely to try fixing process problems
  3043. with slogans and exhortations, and to take behavioral approaches to solving problems
  3044. caused by management (see Appendix, "Blaming Workers for the Results of
  3045. Mismanagement").
  3046. 173
  3047. I should mention that although I'm using the term "Taylorism" in the conventional sense, there is
  3048. considerable evidence that Taylor himself wasn't a Taylorist. Eric Husman of Grim Reader blog helpfully
  3049. referred me to the following article, which places Taylor on a comparatively libertarian part of the scientific
  3050. management spectrum and indicates he was quite friendly to the idea of worker input into the production
  3051. process: Chris Nyland, "Taylorism and the Mutual Gains Strategy," Industrial Relations 37:4 (October
  3052. 1998), pp. 519-542. What is normally called "Taylorism" would more accurately refer to the broader
  3053. "scientific management" movement, which was by no means uniformly authoritarian or managerialist.
  3054. 174
  3055. Waterman and Peters, In Search of Excellence, p. 241.
  3056. 175
  3057. Thomas Frank, One Market Under God: Extreme Capitalism, Market Populism, and the End of
  3058. Economic Democracy (New York: Anchor Books, 2001), p.227.
  3059. Thomas Frank noted the contrast between the empowering rhetoric, the talk about
  3060. "openness" and "flattening hierarchies," and the actual practice of tightening control:
  3061. Plenty of average Americans, having considerable personal experience with the way the
  3062. corporation worked, could easily have made their own contributions to the national conversation about
  3063. the nature of the "business revolution." They could have pointed out that the most noticeable change
  3064. that swept through the workplaces of the late eighties and nineties was the diverging fortunes of top
  3065. management and everyone else; that the workplace was becoming ever more arbitrary; that they
  3066. increasingly worked under an omnipresent threat of instant termination; that regardless of how they
  3067. toiled they seemed always to be losing ground....176
  3068. Talk to many of those blue-collar workers and you will discover that they are quite right to fear the
  3069. "new openness." Great displays of soulfulness by top management, they find, often go hand in hand
  3070. with a species of shop-floor Taylorism so advanced and concentrated as to be almost inhuman.
  3071. Management talks of the liberating power of "craziness"; workers get a life so regimented and
  3072. rationalized that I have even heard rumors, from blue-collar workers whose sensitive managers put
  3073. them on twelve-hour rotating shifts, of deliberate corporate plans to wear them out, shave a year or two
  3074. off their lives, and thus save millions in pension outlays. In this experience, talk of empowerment,
  3075. participation, and reeingineering is followed automatically by intensification of management
  3076. demands.177
  3077. In practice... post-Taylorism generally means intensified Taylorism; workplace
  3078. democracy means getting workers to make efficiency suggestions--efficiency suggestions
  3079. that invariably lead to layoffs or speedup.... Every new theory, new buzzword, new
  3080. movement, new consultant seems... merely to offer another means to the same goal: fewer
  3081. workers, more output.... What is an intellectual playground for an entire class of consultants
  3082. and gurus is, for the vast majority of working Americans, a living hell of surveillance and
  3083. degradation in which every emotion is faked and every response is anticipated.178
  3084. We will reserve for another chapter most discussion of management fads like
  3085. reeingineering, as they affect the actual organization of production. Our main concern in
  3086. this section is with programs aimed at motivating workers.
  3087. Probably the most notorious such programs in recent years have been Who Moved My
  3088. Cheese? and Fish! Philosophy. Who Moved My Cheese? was the premier motivational
  3089. fad of the '90s, and Fish! essentially recycled the very same themes for this decade. As
  3090. the saying goes, I hated the Backstreet Boys back when they called themselves New Kids
  3091. on the Block.
  3092. Actually, many of the themes of WWMC? were foreshadowed in Tom Lagana's
  3093. Chicken Soup series. Lagana and his Chicken Soup books were described in this way by
  3094. the--unfortunately now defunct--Molotov Cocktail for the Soul site:
  3095. Snatching hypocritical victory from the jaws of defeat, this electrical engineer turned
  3096. 176
  3097. Ibid., p. 171.
  3098. Ibid., p. 246.
  3099. 178
  3100. Ibid., p. 248.
  3101. 177
  3102. mind engineer is now complicit with his old "redundancy eliminators." He now helps
  3103. "organizations who want to get the most out of people;" and those people would, of course,
  3104. be the Prozac-plied personnel now doing twice the work they would have at the same
  3105. position twenty years ago and are too sedated to feel the boss's whip cracking across their
  3106. backs. "[Lagana] put a smile on my face and it stayed there even after I went back to work,"
  3107. gushes one successfully sheered sheep, her organization now getting the most out of her. "I
  3108. already feel less stress as I apply some of the techniques," bleated another after scampering
  3109. from a Lagana seminar payed for by the Firm.179
  3110. Lagana repeatedly asked that this "hateful" review be taken down, so apparently it must
  3111. have struck home.
  3112. Who Moved My Cheese?, by Spencer Johnson, was created as a management tool for
  3113. dealing with "change resisters." So naturally, it's a big favorite of HR departments
  3114. everywhere, who order it by the gross for employee consumption.
  3115. In Spencer Johnson's world, change, like cheese, is something that "just happens"; it's
  3116. presented in much the same way Tom Friedman presents "globalization": not as the
  3117. product of human action, but as an inevitable and impersonal force of nature. We're
  3118. expected to accept "change" as it comes, and deal with it within whatever framework is
  3119. established by the anonymous gods in white coats who structure the maze. The fact that
  3120. some authority figures are in a position to dole out cheese, and that we must jump through
  3121. whatever hoops they require in order to get it, goes without saying.
  3122. In fact, Johnson's recipe for "dealing with change in your work and in your life" is a
  3123. lot like the medieval peasant's fatalistic acceptance of one ruler after another, washing
  3124. over him in succession like a series of tidal waves. "Keep your head down, do your work,
  3125. pay your rent, don't look beyond your station in life--and don't, above all, meddle in the
  3126. affairs of the great lords."
  3127. It's also a bit like Parsons' enthusiastic embrace of "change" in 1984: "The chocoration's been increased to 20 grammes. Doubleplusgood, eh?"
  3128. The fundamental, unquestioned assumption of Who Moved My Cheese? is that
  3129. "change" is the prerogative of management, and that it's our job to adjust to it. As
  3130. Thomas Frank pointedly observes, there's one question we're never to ask:
  3131. While most of us must "adapt to change," others get to make change; while most of us
  3132. are expected to smilingly internalize management theory, to learn our place in the world from
  3133. vapid fairy tales, others buy the insulting stuff in bulk in order to cram it down the throats of
  3134. thousands who have the misfortune to work in the bigperson's insurance agency or box
  3135. factory.
  3136. 179
  3137. Rejuvenal, "Molotov Cocktail for Tom Lagana's Soul," July 1998. Molotov Cocktail for the Soul site
  3138. <http://www.connect.ab.ca/~mctsoul/lagana.htm> (defunct--available only through Internet Archive).
  3139. Will the time ever come, Americans might well ask, when we get to move management's
  3140. cheese?
  3141. This assessment of WMMC? is fairly common. Consider these excerpts from my
  3142. favorite Amazon reviews of it:
  3143. If you are a manager who wants to be excused for his/her bad decisions by disguising
  3144. them as "change" that "just happens," this is the book you should make mandatory reading
  3145. for your employees.
  3146. That's how a lot of corporate America works, after all: companies do not make mistakes,
  3147. it's the employees who cannot adapt to "change."
  3148. ***
  3149. This book is wrong. It teaches that you must accept change without regard to whether it
  3150. is appropriate it not. It teaches that you must not struggle, you must not fight. You must
  3151. simply accept whatever change happens. This is the perfect book to distribute when a
  3152. company is going through reorganization....
  3153. ***
  3154. The message of this book is meant to squelch personal ambition and encourage its
  3155. readers to resign themselves to corporate slavery.
  3156. I was especially amused that so many employees have come to recognize their employer's
  3157. distribution, promotion, and forced reading of Who Moved My Cheese? as a prelude to
  3158. layoffs.
  3159. That's the common perception of the book, and if Spencer Johnson's comment in an
  3160. endpaper blurb is any indication, he resents the hell out of it:
  3161. Some even fear it suggests all change is good and that people should mindlessly conform
  3162. to unnecessary changes imposed by others, although that is not in the story.180
  3163. No, it's just implicit in every single page of this wretched little turd of a book. The real
  3164. question is, how could a reader not make such an interpretation?
  3165. First of all, Johnson's pissing and moaning is directly across from a facing page full of
  3166. enthusiastic endorsements from "organizations" that used the book to get their employees'
  3167. minds right. This is our first clue that there might be a hidden agenda. The fact that
  3168. WMMC?'s website is geared toward corporate clients might also raise some eyebrows.
  3169. Like both the earlier Chicken Soup for the Soul series and the later Fish!, the book's prime
  3170. customer is HR departments.
  3171. 180
  3172. Spencer Johnson, Who Moved My Cheese? An A-Mazing Way To Deal With Change In Your Work And
  3173. In Your Life (New York: G.P. Putnam's Sons, 1998, 2002), p. iv.
  3174. As more than one Amazon reviewer noted, the "book" is a heavily marked up piece of
  3175. fluff, specifically designed to be marketed in bulk to HR departments, who in turn pass it
  3176. on to a captive audience of wage-serfs. And a lot of those employees, mindful of Haw's
  3177. slogan "Noticing Small Changes Early Helps You Adapt To The Bigger Changes That
  3178. Are To Come,"181 see the distribution of this book as a prelude to downsizing or a general
  3179. tightening of the screws on the "littlepeople." If your employers start passing out
  3180. WWMC?, just remember what Victor said in that Ren and Stimpy cartoon: "Relax and
  3181. think happy thoughts, because this is really... gonna... HURT!"
  3182. Just about every page of Who Moved My Cheese? has something to bear out the
  3183. interpretation that Johnson finds so objectionable. It is full of examples of people wisely
  3184. adapting to "change" and being rewarded, and obstinate "change resisters" who suffer the
  3185. consequences of their folly. The leading character, Haw, at first questions change and
  3186. then discovers the error of his ways. But there is not one single, solitary example of a
  3187. character questioning change, deciding that it was unjustified, and turning out to be right.
  3188. The only character in the book who even raises the question of who is responsible for
  3189. change and whether it is justified, Hem, is portrayed as unattractively as possible.
  3190. “What? No Cheese?” Hem yelled. He continued yelling, “No Cheese? No Cheese?” as
  3191. though if he shouted loud enough someone would put it back.
  3192. “Who moved my Cheese?” he hollered.
  3193. Finally, he put his hands on his hips, his face turned red, and he screamed at the top of
  3194. his voice, “It’s not fair!”182
  3195. When Hem even raises the question of who moved the cheese, and why, it's portrayed
  3196. as the moral equivalent of a toddler's temper tantrum.
  3197. "Why should we change?" Hem asked. "We're littlepeople. We're special. This sort of
  3198. thing should not happen to us. Or if it does, we should at least get some benefits."
  3199. "Why should we get benefits?" Haw asked.
  3200. "Because we're entitled," Hem claimed....
  3201. "Why?" Haw asked.
  3202. "Because we didn't cause this problem," Hem said. "Somebody else did this and we
  3203. should get something out of it."
  3204. Haw suggested, "Maybe we should simply stop analyzing the situation and go find some
  3205. 181
  3206. 182
  3207. Ibid., p. 68.
  3208. Ibid., p. 33.
  3209. New Cheese?"183
  3210. It's kind of hard to make a reasoned evaluation of whether change is "unnecessary"
  3211. when it's out of bounds even to raise the question of who's responsible for it. For that
  3212. matter, Spencer makes his "change" the work of anonymous forces which are never
  3213. identified, conveniently making the question of who moved the cheese impossible to
  3214. answer. No scientist in a white lab coat ever reaches in to move the cheese. "Change" is
  3215. not the product of human agency--it's just "there." I'm surprised Johnson didn't name his
  3216. "littlepeople" Spit and Swallow, since those seem to be the only possible responses to
  3217. what's done to them.
  3218. It's also hard to imagine, in Johnson's little world, just what the identifying features of
  3219. unnecessary or unjustified change would be, although in his endpaper blurb he appears to
  3220. recognize it as a theoretical possibility (like antimatter or wormholes, or something).
  3221. In fact, Barbara Ehrenreich reads WMMC? in light of another book, QBQ! The
  3222. Question Behind the Question, in which "we are told that questions beginning with 'who'
  3223. or 'why' are symptoms of 'victim thinking.'''184 In every concrete example in this sorry
  3224. excuse for a book, the very act of questioning whether a change is necessary puts one
  3225. squarely in the camp of Hem. For example, consider this anecdote from Ken Blanchard's
  3226. introduction:
  3227. One of the many real-life examples comes from Charlie Jones, a well-respected
  3228. broadcaster for NBC-TV, who revealed that hearing the story of “Who Moved My
  3229. Cheese?” saved his career....
  3230. ...Charlie had worked hard and had done a great job of broadcasting Track and Field
  3231. events at an earlier Olympic Games, so he was surprised and upset when his boss told
  3232. him he’d been removed from these showcase events for the next Olympics and assigned
  3233. to Swimming and Diving.
  3234. Not knowing these sports as well, he was frustrated. He felt unappreciated and he
  3235. became angry. He said he felt it wasn’t fair! His anger began to affect everything he did.
  3236. Then, he heard the story of “Who Moved My Cheese?”
  3237. After that he said he laughed at himself and changed his attitude. He realized his
  3238. boss had just “moved his Cheese.” So he adapted. He learned the two new sports, and in
  3239. the process, found that doing something new made him feel young.
  3240. It wasn’t long before his boss recognized his new attitude and energy, and he soon
  3241. got better assignments. He went on to enjoy more success than ever and was later
  3242. 183
  3243. Ibid., p. 38.
  3244. Barbara Ehrenreich, "Who Moved My Ability to Reason?" The New York Times, August 14, 2005
  3245. <http://www.nytimes.com/2005/08/14/books/review/14EHRENRE.html>.
  3246. 184
  3247. inducted into Pro Football’s Hall of Fame – Broadcaster’s Alley.185
  3248. So Job, though sorely tempted to doubt, finally recognized that the Lord moves in
  3249. mysterious ways, his wonders to perform. And "the LORD blessed the latter end of Job
  3250. more than his beginning..." For Charlie to question his boss was akin to Job questioning
  3251. the voice from the whirlwind. "My boss decided it, I accept it, that settles it."
  3252. And Johnson's own book, apparently, has itself become a form of cheese-moving to
  3253. be accepted without question. As Blanchard put it in his introduction,
  3254. it stimulated their [his employees'] thinking about how they might apply what they'd
  3255. learned to their own situation.186
  3256. See, whether or not they agreed with what they read wasn't even an issue--just how to
  3257. "apply" what "they'd learned."
  3258. The fictionalized Discussion in the last part of the book, between the class reunion
  3259. attendees, includes an extended anecdote by "Michael," the meta-story's fictionalized
  3260. author of the "little story," who invented it to deal with "change resisters" in his own
  3261. "organization." At one point, he actually appears to be about to address the question of
  3262. resisting change imposed from above:
  3263. Well, the further we went into our organization, the more people we found who felt they
  3264. had less power. They were understandably more afraid of what the change imposed from
  3265. above might do to them. So they resisted change.
  3266. In short, a change imposed is a change opposed.
  3267. But having skirted the edge of heresy by raising this question, he apparently dismisses
  3268. it as unworthy of serious consideration. The book helped all these recalcitrants to improve
  3269. their attitude toward change, and the issue of its legitimacy was set aside with no further
  3270. mention:
  3271. But when the Cheese Story was shared with literally everyone in our organization, it
  3272. helped us change the way we looked at change. It helped everyone laugh, or at least smile, at
  3273. their old fears and want to move on.187
  3274. There it is again: management assigns (er, excuse me, "shares") this shitty little book
  3275. to "literally everyone in [the] organization," and they all stop asking about who's
  3276. imposing this change from above, who it benefits, and whether it's a good idea. They get
  3277. their minds right.
  3278. 185
  3279. Ibid., pp. 14-16.
  3280. Ibid., p. 18.
  3281. 187
  3282. Ibid., p. 91.
  3283. 186
  3284. ...practically everyone, those who left and those who stayed, said the Cheese story helped
  3285. them see things differently and cope better.
  3286. Those who had to go out and look for a new job said it was hard at first but recalling the
  3287. story was a great help to them....
  3288. ...[I]nstead of complaining about the changes that were happening, people now said,
  3289. "They just moved our Cheese. Let’s look for the New Cheese." It saved a lot of time and
  3290. reduced stress....188
  3291. I'll just bet it did, at least for management. "They just moved our Cheese. Let's look
  3292. for the New Cheese" is certainly less stressful to hear than "They ran the company into
  3293. the ground, cashed in their stock options just before the earnings report came out, and
  3294. flushed our pension fund down the toilet! Let's lynch the bastards!"
  3295. Before long, the people who had been resisting saw the advantage of changing. They
  3296. even helped bring about change.
  3297. Michael was then asked why he thought this happened. The answer: people naturally
  3298. have a good attitude about getting screwed, in the absence of "peer pressure."
  3299. "I think a lot of it had to do with the kind of peer pressure that can exist in a company.
  3300. “What happens in most organizations you’ve been in when a change is announced by top
  3301. management? Do most people say the change is a great idea or a bad idea?”
  3302. “A bad idea,” Frank answered.
  3303. “Yes,” Michael agreed. “Why?”
  3304. Carlos said, “Because people want things to stay the same and they think the change will
  3305. be bad for them. When one smart person says the change is a bad idea, others say the same.”
  3306. “Yes, they may not really feel that way,” Michael said, “but they agreed in order to look
  3307. smart as well. That’s the sort of peer pressure that fights change in any organization....
  3308. “People changed because no one wanted to look like Hem!”189
  3309. Workers who question a "change... announced by top management" (a change that
  3310. may involve downsizings, a freeze in pay, or a hike in the health insurance deductible),
  3311. are just like the wayward kid in an episode of Davey and Goliath, where Davey is
  3312. pressured to smoke so he can be one of the kewl kidz--or maybe Timmy falling down a
  3313. well, or something, on a dare by one of the "bad kids." The point is, if Davey and Timmy
  3314. would just listen to Mom and Dad, they wouldn't be led into trouble by bad influences.
  3315. 188
  3316. 189
  3317. Ibid., p. 92.
  3318. Ibid., pp. 92-93.
  3319. But there were, alas, still a few Hems who failed to respond to the glorious visions of
  3320. change presented by the Dear Leader. Pay attention, because this is really important:
  3321. "Unfortunately, the Hems were the anchors that slowed us down.... They were either
  3322. too comfortable or too afraid to change. Some of our Hems changed only when they saw
  3323. the sensible [by definition] vision we painted that showed them how changing would
  3324. work to their advantage...."
  3325. "What did you do with the Hems who didn't change?" Frank wanted to know.
  3326. "We had to let them go," Michael said sadly.190
  3327. Again, I've scoured this narrative for the slightest hint that the changes imposed by
  3328. "leaders" could ever be unnecessary or a bad idea. Nothing. In every example in this
  3329. book, the pattern is: Leader imposes change, the Haws get with the program, and the
  3330. Hems get the door. In Laura Lemay's words,
  3331. You will read the cheese book, and you will like the cheese book. It will change your
  3332. life. Or we will fire your ass.191
  3333. Or as Spencer Johnson himself helpfully put it, "all change is good and... people should
  3334. mindlessly conform to unnecessary changes imposed by others."
  3335. While we're on the subject of that Discussion: it probably says a great deal about
  3336. Johnson. Outside of the Bible in a Sunday School class, or Quotations from Chairman
  3337. Mao in a Red Guard study circle, it's hard to imagine any book getting such a relentlessly
  3338. positive and uncritical reception from a group of readers. One almost expects somebody
  3339. to stand up and ask "Mr. Johnson: Your book's sales have the momentum of a runaway
  3340. freight train. How do you explain its popularity?"
  3341. The only conclusion I can draw from all this is that Spencer Johnson is a dishonest,
  3342. cowardly weasel. His book was obviously written, with deliberate intent, to impart the
  3343. very message that he so strenuously disavows: "all change is good and... people should
  3344. mindlessly conform to unnecessary changes imposed by others." He just doesn't have the
  3345. guts to own up to it. So when the kitchen light is clicked on, he furiously scuttles under
  3346. the refrigerator, all the while affecting outrage. He's shocked--shocked!!--that anyone
  3347. could possibly so misconstrue his book as to get the message that he deliberately wrote it
  3348. to convey.
  3349. If anything, Fish! is more vile than WMMC?. The aim of the latter fad was simply to
  3350. 190
  3351. Ibid., p. 86.
  3352. Laura Lemay, "The Cheese Stands Alone" (2001), lauralemay.com.
  3353. http://www.lauralemay.com/essays/cheese.html
  3354. 191
  3355. secure worker acquiescence to the downsizings and increased workloads of the '90s.
  3356. Fish!, on the other hand, seeks to elicit positive enthusiasm from the employee whose
  3357. work conditions have deteriorated so much; in fact, it explicitly stresses the fact that the
  3358. worker is working up positivity and enthusiasm despite his lack of control over working
  3359. conditions. Fish! is an attempt to manufacture intrinsic motivation where there is no
  3360. rational cause for it whatsoever. Its basic purpose was described by C. Wright Mills
  3361. several decades ago:
  3362. To secure and increase the will to work, a new ethic that endows work with more than an
  3363. economic incentive is needed. During war, managers have appealed to nationalism; they
  3364. have appealed in the name of the firm or branch of the office or factory.... They have
  3365. repeatedly writtten that... "job enthusiasm is a hallmark of the American Way." But they
  3366. have not yet found a really sound ideology.
  3367. What they are after is "something in the employee," outwardly manifested in a "mail
  3368. must go through" attitude, "the 'we' attitude," "spontaneous discipline," "employees smiling
  3369. and cheerful."192
  3370. Any clear idea of "morale" requires that the values used as criteria be stated. Two
  3371. relevant values would seem to be the cheerfulness or satisfaction of the worker, and the
  3372. extent of his power to determine the course of his work life....
  3373. In contrast... the "morale" of the human relations expert is the morale of a worker who is
  3374. powerless but nevertheless cheerful.... Assuming that the existing framework of industry is
  3375. unalterable and that the aims of the managers are the aims of everyone, the experts of
  3376. "human relations" do not examine the authoritarian structure of modern industry and the role
  3377. of the worker in it. They define the problem of morale in very limited terms, and by their
  3378. techniques seek to reveal to their managerial clients how they can improve employee morale
  3379. within the existing framework of power. Their endeavor is manipulative.193
  3380. In Fish! Philosophy, unlike WMMC?, mere acquiescence to power is not enough. "It's
  3381. not enough to obey Big Brother, Winston. You must love him." To repeat, its purpose is
  3382. to manufacture intrinsic motivation where there is no objective reason for it. It is to
  3383. evoke, in people with no control over their work and whose wages have been stagnant for
  3384. thirty years, intense feelings of commitment to a vocation. Corinne Maier described the
  3385. principle as she observed it in the French workplace:
  3386. One day, in the middle of a meeting on motivation, I dared to say that the only reason I came
  3387. to work was to put food on the table. There were fifteen seconds of absolute silence, and
  3388. everyone seemed uncomfortable. Even though the French word for work, "travail,"
  3389. etymologically derives from an instrument of torture, it's imperative to let it be known, no
  3390. matter the circumstance, that you are working because you are interested in your work. Even
  3391. when put on the rack for hours on end by your pitiless jailers, you'd better not say
  3392. 192
  3393. C. Wright Mills, White Collar: The American Middle Classes (London, Oxford, New York: Oxford
  3394. University Press, 1951), p. 234.
  3395. 193
  3396. Mills, The Sociological Imagination (New York: Grove Press, Inc., 1959), p.
  3397. otherwise.194
  3398. One thing the Fish! pimps especially want to stamp out is the tendency to distinguish
  3399. one's real life, in which one is in charge of one's own time and follows one's own
  3400. priorities and values, from life inside the corporate walls, in which one executes the tasks
  3401. assigned by a master. Ken Blanchard, in his introduction to Fish!, referred to that heresy
  3402. as the "TGIF mentality." In my opinion Orwell's term "ownlife" is more apt.
  3403. As the book suggests, "When we choose to love the work we do, we can catch our limit of
  3404. happiness, meaning, and fulfillment every day."
  3405. How important is that? Incredibly important, especially when you consider that people
  3406. spend about 75 percent of their adult wake time doing work-related activities--getting ready
  3407. for work, traveling to work, working, contemplating work, and decompressing after work. If
  3408. we spend that much time in that part of our lives, we ought to enjoy it and be energized by it.
  3409. And yet, too many people are trading time on the job to satisfy needs elsewhere; "Thank God
  3410. It's Friday" is still a way of life for many people."195
  3411. "...still a way of life..."? With the structural changes in the workplace--the stagnant
  3412. wages, the downsizings, the insecurity, the increased workloads, the increasing
  3413. authoritarianism and surveillance, even increasing exposure to demeaning, manipulative
  3414. agitrpop like Fish!--it's probably more of a way of life than it's been in decades.
  3415. And what kind of sense does it make to say that the percentage of our lives we're
  3416. forced to spend at work is an argument for identifying with work? The amount of time
  3417. we're forced to spend doing wage labor under the direction of bosses is the result of a
  3418. long series of structural changes, starting with the Enclosures and the forced
  3419. proletarianization of the peasantry on the eve of the Industrial Revolution--structural
  3420. changes carried out by the very same people who today constitute the market for
  3421. demeaning, manipulative gimmicks like Fish! It's likely the slave on a Georgia cotton
  3422. plantation or a Roman latifundium worked more than 75% of his waking hours; does that
  3423. mean he should have tried even harder to like exploitation, to get his mind right and learn
  3424. to enjoy the taste of shit? It's certainly a great way, though, to divert workers from
  3425. directly addressing the causes for their jobs colonizing the rest of their lives, and just
  3426. adapt to it. That's probably why it's such a favorite with HR departments.
  3427. Far beyond even the mere substitution of extrinsic for intrinsic motivation, Fish! is a
  3428. way to save management the cost of providing even extrinsic motivation, by manipulating
  3429. the worker into liking whatever he gets: "learning to love what we [sic] do, even if at the
  3430. moment we may not be doing exactly what we [sic] love."196 Chester Barnard's
  3431. 194
  3432. Corinne Maier, Bonjour Laziness: Why Hard Work Doesn't Pay. Translated by Sophie Hawkes (New
  3433. York: Vintage Books, 2005), p. 34.
  3434. 195
  3435. Blanchard introduction, in Stephen C. Lundin, Harry Paul, and John Christensen, Fish! A Remarkable
  3436. Way to Boost Morale and Improve Results (New York: Hyperion, 2000), pp. 9-10.
  3437. 196
  3438. Ibid., p. 11.
  3439. discussion of coercion as a way to adjust the worker to make previously insufficient
  3440. levels of motivation sufficient (see Chapter Six) is relevant here.
  3441. The theme of powerlessness is central to Fish!. The theme is repeatedly stated, not
  3442. only in the book itself:...
  3443. There is always a choice about the way you do your work, even if there is not a choice
  3444. about the work itself.197
  3445. We don't have a lot to do with selecting the work that needs to be done, but we can
  3446. choose how we approach that work.198
  3447. ...but in the even more dumbed-down literature of institutional Fish! programs:
  3448. We can either give in to external events and pressures, few of which we can control, or
  3449. we can take control of our own happiness. Our choices are, after all, the only things that no
  3450. one can take from us in this world.199
  3451. Many of us believe our attitudes are caused directly by outside influences like unpleasant
  3452. experiences or negative people. While these things may act as triggers for our feelings, we
  3453. can choose to either be subservient to these events, few of which we can control, or we can
  3454. take charge of our own responses.200
  3455. We can't control what happens to us, but we do have a choice about how we respond.201
  3456. You can’t always control what happens, but you can control how you respond.202
  3457. You can’t always control circumstances, but you can control your own thoughts.203
  3458. Powerful people control events. Powerless people control their attitudes about those
  3459. events. It's that simple.
  3460. Fish! Philosophy is a lesson from the powerful to the powerless. It involves an
  3461. enormous sleight of hand, carried out through that ubiquitous word "we." One of the
  3462. 197
  3463. Ibid., p. 36.
  3464. Ibid., p. 58.
  3465. 199
  3466. Fish Philosophy official site
  3467. <http://www.charthouse.com/ffc/goods_collegiateCapsule_choose.asp?whoenter=>.
  3468. 200
  3469. "The Fish Philosophy," New South Wales Country Areas Program
  3470. <http://www.cap.nsw.edu.au/QI/TOOLS/def/fishphil.html>.
  3471. 201
  3472. "Fish Philosophy," Mr. Stepien's Science Page, Buffalo Academy of the Sacred Heart
  3473. <http://www.myteacherpages.com/webpages/RStepien/fish.cfm>.
  3474. 202
  3475. "Create a Great Work Environment," A Special Report (Council of State Governments--West)
  3476. <http://www.csgwest.org/Publications/s_rep_work.pdf>.
  3477. 203
  3478. "Appreciative Inquiry: Application and Celebration. Two WLA Sessions presented at Wisconsin Dells
  3479. Conference, 2006" (Wisconsin Library Association)
  3480. <http://www.wla.lib.wi.us/conferences/2006/documents/wlahandouts2006.pdf>.
  3481. 198
  3482. Fish! reviewers at Amazon.Com drew, as the central message of the book: "since you're
  3483. being raped, you might as well enjoy it." In the bizarro world of Fish!, the rapist and the
  3484. victim are equally powerless: "Gee, I sure hate doing this to you. If only there were some
  3485. other way.... Ah, well, at least we can both have a good attitude about it!" And to be sure,
  3486. the rapist usually manages to accommodate himself to his fate.
  3487. Fish!, by sleight of hand, conceals the elephant in the living room: "we" are not all
  3488. equally powerless in the face of circumstances. Some people make circumstances, and
  3489. some people adjust to circumstances.
  3490. Take, for example, the godawful "Third Floor" in the Fish! narrative, which the
  3491. protagonist is brought in to turn around. The bank's management, as the book repeatedly
  3492. stresses, is horrified at the negative atmosphere on that floor.
  3493. Words like unresponsive, entitlement, zombie, unpleasant, slow, wasteland, and negative
  3494. were used frequently to describe this group....
  3495. Supervisors swapped stories about the latest fiasco on the third floor.204
  3496. But golly, why is management being so negative about the atmosphere on the Third
  3497. Floor? Isn't the whole lesson of Fish! that they're supposed to learn to love it? They can't
  3498. control what employees on the Third Floor do, but they can choose their attitude about it.
  3499. Oh, wait.... that's right. It's only those on the bottom who must adjust their attitudes to
  3500. circumstances imposed on them by others; those at the top, on the other hand, get to
  3501. adjust reality to suit their own attitudes.
  3502. To grasp just how presumptuous Fish! really is, just try a thought experiment:
  3503. imagine management's reaction if the circumstances were reversed. Imagine the bosses'
  3504. reaction if you and your coworkers matter-of-factly announced that, henceforth, you
  3505. would be working at a slower pace for the same amount of money, or that you would be
  3506. receiving a higher hourly wage. Imagine telling the boss "you can't do anything about
  3507. these changes, but you can choose to have a good attitude about them!" My guess your
  3508. boss would demonstrate in short order that he does have control over events, and that it's
  3509. not his attitude that has to be adjusted. That's because, while you may be powerless, your
  3510. bosses most certainly are not.
  3511. This assymetrical power relationship is implicit in Fish! Philosophy. And you'd better
  3512. believe that the people who push it are fully aware of their agenda. If you have any doubts
  3513. of what the agenda is, and who's pushing it, just Google "Fish! Philosophy"+"your
  3514. organization." As with Who Moved My Cheese?, the people who control organizations
  3515. are the primary market for Fish!, and the audiences they buy it for are the "human
  3516. resources" they manage.
  3517. 204
  3518. Lundin et al., Fish!, p. 18.
  3519. They are the ones who do things. We are the ones that things are done to. Learn to
  3520. enjoy it, or else. That's the message of Fish! Philosophy.
  3521. We saw the common theme, on the left side of the comma in all those snippets quoted
  3522. above, that we "can't control" what happens to us. But there's a second part to the slogan:
  3523. we can "control how we respond," or "control our own thoughts." In short, we can
  3524. "Choose Our Attitude." And what "attitude" is it we are to "choose"? Why, taking the
  3525. interests of management as our own and doing everything to maximize our output for
  3526. their gain! Like Aristotle's idealized slave, the worker must become a living tool, an
  3527. obedient instrument of goals and priorities chosen by someone else.
  3528. The Fish! authors, quoting John Gardner, unwittingly give a glimpse of the man
  3529. behind the curtain:
  3530. There is something I know about you that you may not even know about yourself. You
  3531. have within you more resources of energy than have ever been tapped, more talent than has
  3532. ever been exploited, more strength than has ever been tested, and more to give than you have
  3533. ever given.205
  3534. And we will take, and take, and take, until you have given every last drop you have to
  3535. give, and then we will replace you. Reading the quote above, I can't help thinking of the
  3536. human batteries in The Matrix.
  3537. The reason for burnout in most workplaces is that management has deliberately and
  3538. systematically downsized staffing levels, trying to get more and more work out of fewer
  3539. and fewer people. The management of the average corporation manufactures burned out
  3540. employees like Carter manufactures liver pills. Through Fish! Philosophy, management
  3541. attempts to deal with burnout entirely through cheerleading and slogans--Stakhanovism-without having to increase staffing levels or pay, or otherwise alter its own contribution to
  3542. the problem. Fish! Philosophy, at its core, is an attempt to get something for nothing.
  3543. Burnout is the natural reaction to prolonged stress: a survival mechanism that
  3544. involves shutting down, withdrawing, and breaking connections to the sources of stressful
  3545. stimuli. It's what happens when people are doing their own work plus that of the
  3546. downsized, often with no time for meal breaks, with less and less control over the
  3547. structure and pacing of their jobs. Fish! Philosophy reminds me a lot of the military's
  3548. attempts at creating pharmacologically engineered super-soldiers, robocops who can go
  3549. 72 hours without sleep and never feel guilt or develop PTSD. In both cases, it's an
  3550. artificial attempt to squeeze more out of people who've been pushed to the breaking point,
  3551. rather than doing anything about the stresses they're subjected to.
  3552. In such an environment, all the motivational appeals to serving internal and external
  3553. customers, and viewing coworkers in other departments as part of the same team, is a sick
  3554. 205
  3555. Ibid., p. 51.
  3556. joke. When the workforce in every department are systematically deprived of the staffing
  3557. levels needed to do an adequate job, they naturally come to see any source of additional
  3558. work as the enemy. Every request from an external or internal customer is another weight
  3559. added to an unbearable load. Workers see increased business as nothing but an increase
  3560. in their already intolerable workload, from which management or shareholders will
  3561. appropriate all the increased income for themselves, and workers will never see a dime of
  3562. increased income. Therefore, they are increasingly hostile to the customer, and seek to
  3563. avoid extra effort at all costs. At the same time, different departments see each other as
  3564. sources of additional work, and attempt to push off their insupportable workloads off on
  3565. each other. A cooperative social order breaks down in an atmosphere of scarcity.
  3566. A good example is a 1973 experiment based on the Biblical story of the Good
  3567. Samaritan. Seminary students were assigned a short talk on a Biblical theme, and sent to
  3568. a nearby building to deliver it. On the way, they encountered a person who appeared to
  3569. be seriously ill and unconscious. The one variable that affected their willingness to stop
  3570. and help was whether they'd been told they were late and needed to hurry, or whether
  3571. they'd been told they had time to spare. Only 10% of those who were told they were late
  3572. stopped to help, as opposed to 65% of those who felt they had plenty of time.206
  3573. Likewise, understaffing and increased workloads inevitably pit workers against each
  3574. other and against the customer. For the stressed out worker in a downsized organization,
  3575. any potential source of additional work is viewed as one drowning man views another
  3576. pulling him down. All the official management happy talk about "internal customers" to
  3577. the contrary, all the smarmy rhetoric about the "golden rule" in the "core values"
  3578. statement, is just so much hypocritical blather. Under those conditions, management's
  3579. cynical exhortations to "teamwork" are about as effective as throwing a bone into a yard
  3580. full of hungry dogs and then saying "y'all play nice now, y'hear?"
  3581. Here's the thing: management doesn't care about what they've done to people, or
  3582. whether it's right or wrong. And they don't care about internal or external customers, or
  3583. their mission statements (and vision and values statements, either). What they care about
  3584. is management featherbedding--more and more quality and process improvement
  3585. committees--and the value of their stock options. All their oleaginous Hallmark Cards
  3586. rhetoric notwithstanding, both the production worker and the customer are means to an
  3587. end for them. They're riding the gravy train, and they want to keep right on riding it. To
  3588. keep the things that matter to them, they have to keep us running on the treadmill. And
  3589. when they notice we're not putting out like we used to, they need to figure out what
  3590. buttons to push to get their human resources back to producing value-added. Fish!
  3591. Philosophy is a way of pushing those buttons.
  3592. That's what it's all about: squeezing more effort out of fewer people, without
  3593. increasing their pay. Management helpfully informed us, in the monthly official happy
  3594. 206
  3595. Jeffrey Nielsen, The End of Leadership, pp. 42-43.
  3596. talk newsletter at the hospital where I work, that "if we [sic] choose to provide
  3597. extraordinary patient care" we could do do, "regardless of our [sic] abundance or lack of
  3598. resources." This is reminiscent of Pharaoh, decreeing that the Hebrew slaves continue to
  3599. make as many bricks as before, "regardless of their abundance or lack of straw." This
  3600. was the same management, by the way, who were high-fiving each other behind closed
  3601. doors on their successful downsizing at the very same time they were churning out
  3602. saccharine motivational agitprop. While they were publicly gushing that we were their
  3603. "most important asset," all of us one big happy "team," they were privately
  3604. congratulating each other on how effectively they'd screwed us over and got away with it.
  3605. It's interesting to hear the fictionalized managers in Fish! complain about the sense of
  3606. "entitlement" on the Third Floor. After all, management's sense of entitlement comes
  3607. through loud and clear in Fish! Management is entitled to a workforce that's enthusiastic
  3608. and dedicated and constantly goes the extra mile, regardless of how it gets screwed.
  3609. Management is entitled to a workforce that greets every new steaming pile with a joyous
  3610. cry of "Oh, boy! Shit again!" Management is entitled to something for nothing.
  3611. It's important to take note of the dog that doesn't bark. A moral tale told by someone
  3612. in a position of authority, with the intention of inculating some attitude in those subject to
  3613. that authority, is a lot like a magic act. What's important is the part of the act that the
  3614. illusionist doesn't want you to see--or the part of the story that's left out. As in Who
  3615. Moved My Cheese?, the one subject the Fish! authors strenuously try to avert attention
  3616. from is the nature and causes of this objective reality that we're supposed to adjust our
  3617. attitudes to.
  3618. Issues of power, ownership and control are entirely absent from the Fish! book.
  3619. Things just are the way they are, like the moving cheese, as the result of blind impersonal
  3620. forces; even to ask the identity of those forces is an act of insubordination. The fact that
  3621. our society has been transformed from one made up almost entirely of the self-employed,
  3622. to one in which giant authoritarian hierarchies control the vast majority's access to
  3623. livelihood, goes completely unremarked.
  3624. In one of the most obscene parts of the book, one character, Lonnie, actually
  3625. compares the homely atavism of his grandmother's kitchen to the modern corporate
  3626. workplace, as an illustration of "choosing your attitude," as if the two were remotely
  3627. comparable.
  3628. Let me tell you about my grandmother. She always brought love and a smile to her work.
  3629. All of us grandkids wanted to help in the kitchen because washing dishes with Grandma was
  3630. so much fun. In the process a great deal of kitchen wisdom was dispensed. Us kids were
  3631. given something truly precious, a caring adult.
  3632. I realize now that my grandma didn't love dishwashing. She brought love to
  3633. dishwashing, and her spirit was infectious.207
  3634. There's one big difference between Grandma's kitchen and the contemporary
  3635. corporate workplace: the word "her." It was her kitchen. It was her dishes. She didn't
  3636. have a boss. She could control how she did the dishes, not just in the lame sense of how
  3637. enthusiastic an attitude she chose to adopt, but in the real sense of how fast she washed,
  3638. how many spells of work she wanted to break the job up into and how long to rest in
  3639. between, what order she washed them in, whether she had separate sinks of wash water
  3640. and rinse water, what kind of soap to use, whether to dry them with a towel or let them air
  3641. dry, etc.--all the decisions you'd better believe a boss would make for her if she was on a
  3642. time clock. And unlike the wage serf in the corporate workplace, she was working
  3643. entirely for herself and her family: she was washing the dishes that she and her loved
  3644. one's ate off of, and she and her family appropriated all the benefits from washing them.
  3645. If Grandma worked in a corporate kitchen, using a hellish institutional dishwasher; if
  3646. the kitchen staff were downsized until Grandma was handling the load previously
  3647. handled by three dishwashers, and the dishes just kept piling up faster than she could
  3648. wash them; if there were repeated inservice meetings and "counsellings" over the kitchen
  3649. staff's failure to keep up with the increased workload; if she went three years in a row
  3650. without a cost-of-living raise because "these are lean times and the organization can't
  3651. afford it," while the CEO's stock options went through the roof and he made a bigger
  3652. bonus than she'd earn in a lifetime; and if all this time she and her coworkers were
  3653. barraged with relentlessly upbeat propaganda about "choosing our attitude" and our "core
  3654. values".... Well, I'm guessing that Grandma would probably get through her shift about
  3655. the same way I do at the hospital where I work: by muttering "God damn this place. God
  3656. damn this place. God damn this place. God damn this place" the whole eight hours, and
  3657. damning the entire management team to hell by name as well.
  3658. The difference between work, as it existed in a society of free and self-employed
  3659. producers, and the job, is exactly the difference between self-directed learning and the
  3660. schooling one receives inside a K-12 prison. The one is an expression of one's self, in a
  3661. world under one's own control; the other requires internalizing a set of goals imposed by
  3662. others, out of their own self-interest. To seriously equate the one with the other requires
  3663. an almost superhuman feat of false consciousness.
  3664. Colin Ward quotes Nigel Balchin, a novelist who was invited to address a conference
  3665. on incentives in industry.
  3666. Industrial psychologists must stop messing about with tricky and ingenious bonus schemes
  3667. and find out why a man, after a hard day's work, went home and enjoyed digging in his
  3668. garden.208
  3669. 207
  3670. 208
  3671. Ibid., pp. 37-38.
  3672. Colin Ward, Anarchy in Action (London: Freedom Press, 1982), p. 95.
  3673. The answer, of course, was that it was his garden, and he worked it to suit himself
  3674. without a boss looking over his shoulder.
  3675. The good Lord may have sentenced us to earn our bread by the sweat of our brow, but
  3676. he never said anything about being harassed while we were doing it by some peckerhead
  3677. in a suit and tie. An anarchist whose program appeared on the local cable access channel
  3678. once made a very pointed observation: it's wired into us, she said, when somebody
  3679. follows us around and won't stop bugging the shit out of us, to do one of two things-either get away from them, or beat the crap out of them. A situation in which we're
  3680. bugged by a boss for eight hours a day, with this "fight or flight" instinct revving our
  3681. nervous and endocrine systems at 80 mph in first gear, is something we're not designed
  3682. for by the evolutionary process.
  3683. For the Fish! authors, the unpleasantness of a job has absolutely nothing to do with
  3684. the objective conditions created by those in authority. For example, the authors never
  3685. spend a moment considering why the Third Floor has such abysmally low morale.
  3686. There's obviously no cause or reason--it happened "just because." So obviously, the only
  3687. thing needed to fix it is for the staff to get their minds right, without regard to any change
  3688. in objective, external reality. And management, seemingly, are the only parties who don't
  3689. have a choice. None of their decisions or policies has anything to do with whether the job
  3690. is a humanly tolerable one, or whether it is an overstressed, understaffed shithole. They
  3691. have no choice but to react negatively when they can't get more work out of people for the
  3692. same pay--it's just the objective nature of things. So while management lives in a world
  3693. bounded by material constraints and limited by objective conditions, workers live in a
  3694. world created entirely by pure thought.
  3695. Another character in the book, Wolf, actually compares working conditions to a car
  3696. wreck, and his choice of attitude during recovery to one's choice of attitude in the
  3697. workplace.209 There's one big difference, though. The race car wasn't a conscious being
  3698. with a will. It wasn't "treating" him any way. And it especially wasn't trying to
  3699. manipulate him into "choosing" to have a good attitude about being hurt, so it could hurt
  3700. him again more easily in the future. "Change" isn't something that "just happens" like a
  3701. car wreck. It's something done by conscious agents with an agenda, to promote their own
  3702. perceived self-interest.
  3703. As Barbara Ehrenreich demonstrated in Bait and Switch, the required attitudes of
  3704. relentless upbeat enthusiasm and embrace of authority extend to everyone in the job
  3705. market--not just those actively employed. For example, participants at one "executive
  3706. boot camp" were taught in no uncertain terms to take responsibility for all success and
  3707. failure; anyone giving the slightest hint that structural forces or a sysem of power might
  3708. be at work quickly learned that they'd touched the third rail: they'd questioned the cheesemover. Patrick, the counselor, relentlessly cut off any reference to external or
  3709. 209
  3710. Fish!, p. 80.
  3711. institutional conditions.
  3712. ...Billy... observes briskly, "They want ten to fourteen hours a day now.... It's a
  3713. challenge."
  3714. "They?" Patrick interrupts. "Who are they?"
  3715. It turns out that we are not to talk about "them"; we are to confine ourselves to speaking
  3716. "experientially".... The market is of no interest to us; it's just another "they"--some external
  3717. force or entity that can be used as an excuse for our failures.
  3718. The job search industry, apparently, has a lot in common with the "name it and claim it!"
  3719. culture of Pentecostal TV preachers and the "blame the victim" philosophy--so beloved of
  3720. Oprah Winfrey--in The Law of Success. In response to one personal account of
  3721. impending layoffs and the dangers involved in going into business for oneself,
  3722. Patrick "freezes" Kevin and turns to us: "The person who is stopping Kevin is who?"
  3723. Everyone, myself excepted, answers in unison: "Kevin!"210
  3724. This is exactly the attitude demanded by Who Moved My Cheese? and Fish!. And in
  3725. a world where so much obviously unfair "change" has been imposed from above by those
  3726. who benefit from the injustice, the beneficiaries desperately need for us to accept the
  3727. "change" with a "good attitude." As we saw with Fish!, a sense of powerlessness and
  3728. acceptance is a virtue of the ruled:
  3729. Cheerfulness, upbeatness and compliance: these are the qualities of subordinates--of
  3730. servants rather than masters....211
  3731. ...[F]rom the point of view of the economic "winners"... the view that one's fate depends
  3732. entirely on oneself must be remarkably convenient. It explains the winners' success in the
  3733. most flattering terms while invalidating the complaint of the losers. Patrick's clients, for
  3734. example, came to the boot camp prepared to blame their predicament on the economy, or the
  3735. real estate market, or the inhuman corporate demands on their time. But these culprits were
  3736. summarily dismissed in favor of alleged individual failings: depression, hesitation, lack of
  3737. focus. It's not the world that needs changing, is the message, it's you. No need, then, to band
  3738. together to work for a saner economy or a more human-friendly corporate environment, or to
  3739. band together at all.212
  3740. The culture of the corporate job search industry also requires that the would-be
  3741. cubicle returnee maintain the habits, even in unemployment, of organizing his life around
  3742. a job. In other words, the job search must be treated as a job in itself:
  3743. 210
  3744. Barbara Ehrenreich, Bait and Switch: The (Futile) Pursuit of the American Dream (New York:
  3745. Metropolitan Books, Henry Holt and Company, 2005), pp. 70-71.
  3746. 211
  3747. Ibid., p. 230.
  3748. 212
  3749. Ibid., p. 85.
  3750. You have to structure it hierarchically, complete with someone playing the role of boss....
  3751. Thus the one great advantage of unemployment--the freedom to do as you please, to get u
  3752. when you want, wear what you want, and let your mind drift here and there--is foreclosed.
  3753. Just when you finally have a chance to be fully autonomous and possibly creative, for a few
  3754. months anyway, you have to invent a little drama in which you are still toiling away for the
  3755. man.213
  3756. This sheds a great deal of light on the aversion of "HR professionals" to periods of selfemployment or any other "gaps" in one's resume. The danger is that the human resource
  3757. may no longer have his mind right, that he has gotten out of the habit of viewing himself
  3758. as someone else's property under the corrupting influence of being a "masterless man."
  3759. The frequent admonitions on attitude go beyond any simple, common-sense warnings to
  3760. behave pleasantly in an interview, and instead demand that positive feelings be fully
  3761. internalized. One website catering to the white-collar job search culture warns that any
  3762. "negative attitude"--like anger toward a former employer--will show despite your best effort
  3763. to correct it.214
  3764. In short, all the "flexibility" and "openness to change," all the positive attitude, are
  3765. entirely one-sided. The worker is obligated to "think happy thoughts" about whatever is
  3766. done to him, but is entitled to appeal to absolutely no corresponding obligation on the part
  3767. of those with power. The worker's duty was ably summed up by Julia O'Connell
  3768. Davidson: "Employers require workers to be both dependable and disposable."
  3769. Managers themselves, of course, for the most part do not take such motivational
  3770. blather seriously.
  3771. High morale is variously thought to improved productivity or, at the least, to "make for a
  3772. family spirit." Only a few managers are willing to voice what a top official of Weft
  3773. Corporation thinks is actually a widespread managerial sentiment about workers' happiness:
  3774. "Let them be happy on their own time."215
  3775. More than a few workers see through all the official happy talk, as well. For example,
  3776. one worker's reaction to a "corporate culture" campaign at a heavy vehicle manufacturing
  3777. company in Lancashire: "They give the impression we work together when it suits them,
  3778. but when it gets rough, we're the ones who get it."216
  3779. A good example is Robert Jackall's "Covenant" corporation, the locus of the great
  3780. 213
  3781. Ibid., p. 89.
  3782. Ibid., p. 220.
  3783. 215
  3784. Robert Jackall, Moral Mazes: The World of Corporate Managers (New York: Oxford University Press,
  3785. 1988), p. 138.
  3786. 216
  3787. David Collinson, "Strategies of Resistance: Power, Knowledge, and Subjectivity in the Workplace," in
  3788. J. Jermier and D. Knights, eds., Resistance and Power in Organizations (London: routledge, 1994), p. 33.
  3789. 214
  3790. downsizing described earlier in this chapter. Immediately after the purge of 600
  3791. Covenant employees, and in the midst of all the Byzantine maneuverings, betrayals, and
  3792. other bureaucratic warfare fought to avoid responsibility for losses during the 1982
  3793. recession, the company held a "Family Day." Afterward, the CEO bloviated:
  3794. I think Family Day made a very strong statement about the [Covenant] "family" of
  3795. employees at [Corporate Headquarters]. And that is that we can accomplish whatever we set
  3796. out to do if we work together; if we share the effort, we will share the rewards. The "New
  3797. World of [Covenant]" has no boundaries only frontiers, and each and everyone can play a
  3798. role, for we need what you have to contribute.217
  3799. "Lenin," of Lenin's Tomb, gives an inside reaction to his experiences with Fish!-like
  3800. attempts at "fun" on the job:
  3801. Today is dress-down Friday. Don't forget the funny tie or the outlandish hat. Don't forget
  3802. the ribtickling Kermit the Frog shirt. Friday is funday. These employers really take the
  3803. fucking piss, don't they? Not content with sucking the lifeblood out of you for the working
  3804. day and tacitly getting free overtime out of you (they call it 'flexibility', almost as if your free
  3805. labour was a fact about your personality, something you willingly and charitably part with
  3806. because you aren't one of those inflexible assholes), they have the nerve to try and structure
  3807. your fun. Office drinks with people you fucking hate, at which you can expect flirting from
  3808. middle managers who would ordinarily be pushing you around, and fun-filled news items
  3809. about other departments in the company that you didn't ask for and you don't need. Days out,
  3810. where you are invited to humiliate yourself in some sporting event like bowling or baseball
  3811. while getting slowly drunk. Team games, the weekly cake whip-round, the birthday cards.
  3812. Your fun. Your affections. Often your time. On their orders. Apparently, this sort of thing
  3813. boosts productivity and team cohesion, but it seems more likely that it reinforces an
  3814. ideological norm of cheerful willingness to be fucked around, to participate in official lies, to
  3815. tolerate hypocritical wall-to-wall grins and bonhomie with people who will tomorrow be
  3816. undermining you or overworking you by any means possible. Hey - you don't want to be a
  3817. bad sport do you?
  3818. In one of my previous jobs, shortly before a wave of redundancies that caught yours
  3819. truly, the manager thought it was a good idea for an Easter fun stunt to travel round the
  3820. country in a bunny outfit with a dull power-point presentation filled with appalling attempts
  3821. at humour. He called it the 'Mad Hatters Tea Party' (there was cake and various beverages). I
  3822. mean it. He really did that shit. If I'd had time to prepare for this absurdity, I'd have been
  3823. waiting with a shotgun behind the door: "Hewwo wabbit!" As it is, the worst that happened
  3824. to him was a ubiquitous blank non-committal stare that the British seem to have honed to
  3825. perfection, and which disarms bogus humorists in seconds. I believe I did my part. Why do
  3826. we put up with this? Why don't we reassert our right to be miserable bastards? Be a bad
  3827. sport. Be uncooperative. Be inflexible. Be prepared to poop a party in an instant. Hey, if you
  3828. want some real fun, unionise the place, strike and drive them out of business. It's the best
  3829. years of your life they're sucking out of you, dammit.218
  3830. 217
  3831. Jackall, Moral Mazes, p. 37.
  3832. Lenin, "Capitalism Orders You to Have Fun," Lenin's Tomb, December 7, 2007
  3833. <http://leninology.blogspot.com/2007/12/capitalism-orders-you-to-have-fun.html>.
  3834. 218
  3835. Management's real attitude toward employee relations and motivation is probably best
  3836. summed up by this little anecdote:
  3837. At the Manhattan offices of Steelcase, Inc., an office furniture-maker, workers and
  3838. visitors are greeted in the lobby by a 6-by-4-foot ant farm: ...[I]t was chosen by the company
  3839. to make a statement about work. In an article in the Wall Street Journal..., the company said
  3840. it was looking for a metaphor to describe how people live and work. "Work is dramatically
  3841. different than it used to be," Steelcase manager Dave Lathrop told the Journal. "For more
  3842. people, work and nonwork are blending." He explained that the company liked that the ants
  3843. were able to "silently represent that, simply by doing what they do."219
  3844. Appendix 8A
  3845. Blaming Workers for the Results of Mismanagement
  3846. "Employee error," increasingly, is scapegoated for whatever goes wrong in today's
  3847. downsized, understaffed, sped-up workplace. Four items on the same theme:
  3848. 1. SENATORS WERE WARNED OF LEXINGTON AIR CONTROLLER
  3849. UNDERSTAFFING220
  3850. JEFFREY MCMURRAY, ABC NEWS - Months before the Comair jet crash that
  3851. killed 49 people, air traffic controllers at the Lexington airport wrote to federal officials
  3852. complaining about a hostile working environment in the tower and short-staffing on the
  3853. overnight shift, according to letters obtained by The Associated Press. In identical letters
  3854. sent April 4 to Kentucky's senators, Republicans Mitch McConnell and Jim Bunning, a
  3855. control tower worker said the overnight shift, or "mid," is staffed with two people "only
  3856. when convenient to management."
  3857. The Federal Aviation Administration's guidelines called for two people to be there
  3858. the morning of the Aug. 27 crash, but only one was present. "We had a controller retire
  3859. last month and now we are back to single man mids," wrote Faron Collins, a union leader
  3860. for the Lexington control tower workers. "I ask you one simple question. Are two people
  3861. needed on the mids for safety or not? If they are, why are they not scheduled?" . . .
  3862. Besides the letter to the senators, another Lexington control tower operator wrote to the
  3863. FAA's Accountability Board on Dec. 1, 2005, complaining about a hostile work
  3864. environment in the tower. That employee requested anonymity, fearing discipline against
  3865. him.
  3866. 219
  3867. Daniel S. Levine, Disgruntled: The Darker Side of the World of Work (New York: Berkley Boulevard
  3868. Books, 1998), p. 237.
  3869. 220
  3870. ABC News <http://abcnews.go.com/US/wireStory?id=2427312&CMP=OTC-RSSFeeds0312>. Link
  3871. now dead. Originally linked in Progressive Review; quotes are from originally quoted text preserved in
  3872. blog post: Kevin Carson, "Blaming Workers for the Results of Mismanagement," Mutualist Blog, Sept. 17,
  3873. 2006 <http://mutualist.blogspot.com/2006/09/blaming-workers-for-results-of.html>.
  3874. 2. Dian Hardison. "I F-ing Warned Them!"221
  3875. I told them that the technicians and engineers were overworked. I told them that
  3876. there were too many managers and too many meetings and "dog-and-pony" shows. I told
  3877. them that their senior "face time" play games, while they spent all their time plotting how
  3878. to give each other pay raises, and left the guys on the floor to struggle day to day with
  3879. obsolete and overpriced and unqualified equipment, was going to result in another
  3880. Challenger.
  3881. I was there for Challenger.
  3882. I saw the same exact conditions happening again. Overpaid, lazy, irresponsible
  3883. managers concerned solely with their climbing up their ladders.
  3884. I told them they were skimping on inspections. I told them that the ground crews
  3885. were asleep on their feet from exhaustion. I made as much noise as I knew how to make
  3886. about the top-heavy bureaucracy sitting around in their fancy panelled offices, giving
  3887. whorish press interviews in their smugness, while they did not have a clue what was
  3888. going on in the real world where I was working....
  3889. Like Challenger, those who are most guilty are the ones who will attempt to make
  3890. the most political capital out of it. But the blame for Columbia lies entirely and totally
  3891. with the NASA administrators. They should all be investigated for their criminal
  3892. negligence. They should all serve time in jail.
  3893. 3. MSHA Makes The "Wrong Decision" To Blame Workers For Accidents222
  3894. That management likes to blame worker behavior for accidents will come as no
  3895. surprise to American workers. That this "blame the worker" theory is not consistent with
  3896. the facts, that it doesn't get to the root causes of workplace incidents is also not a surprise
  3897. to American workers.
  3898. So this new Mine Safety and Health Administration program comes as a great
  3899. surprise to all of us.
  3900. MSHA Launches New Safety and Health Initiative223
  3901. ARLINGTON, Va.- The U.S. Department of Labor's Mine Safety and Health
  3902. Administration (MSHA) today launched "Make the Right Decision," a safety and health
  3903. initiative that helps miners and mine operators focus on human factors, such as decision-
  3904. 221
  3905. Dian Hardison, "Shuttle Crash & Smug NASA Managers 'I F-ing Warned Them!'" Counterpunch, Feb.
  3906. 1, 2003 <http://www.counterpunch.org/hardison02012003.html>.
  3907. 222
  3908. "MSHA Makes The 'Wrong Decision' To Blame Workers For Accidents," Labor Blog, July 28, 2005
  3909. <http://www.nathannewman.org/laborblog/archive/003252.shtml>.
  3910. 223
  3911. Department of Labor press release, "MSHA Launches New Safety and Health Initiative," July 13,
  3912. 2005 <http://www.msha.gov/MEDIA/PRESS/2005/NR050713.asp>.
  3913. making, when at work. The campaign encourages miners and mine management to work
  3914. together on safety and health issues.
  3915. "MSHA will increase its focus on safety decisions during this campaign, which is
  3916. not a limited-time initiative," said David G. Dye, deputy assistant secretary of labor for
  3917. mine safety and health. "We want miners and management to make the right decisions to
  3918. ensure the safety and health of America's miners."
  3919. So what's the problem with encouraging workers to make the right decision?
  3920. First, the assumption of this program is that most accident happen because workers
  3921. make the wrong decisions. In other words, all you need is a little education, training and
  3922. enlightenment and all will be well. If accidents continue to happen, they're caused by
  3923. worker carelessness, incompetence, stupidity, suicidal tendencies -- and just plain dumb
  3924. decisions.
  3925. In other words, "Make the Right Decision" is just your same old "behavioral safety"
  3926. program under a new name. Behavioral safety theories say that worker carelessness or
  3927. misconduct is the cause of most accidents, and disciplining workers is the answer. But
  3928. behavioral theories don't hold up to a closer look at the root causes of most workplace
  3929. accidents: generally management system and organizational problems that lead to unsafe
  3930. conditions....
  3931. So what about these two "unavoidable accidents" reported last year? Would they be
  3932. alive today if they had just made the right decision?
  3933. Two miners killed in pair of incidents
  3934. After badly burning his hands in a coal-mining accident earlier this year in Perry
  3935. County, Edwin Pennington said he was finished with mining work, but he returned for
  3936. the money, his father said yesterday.
  3937. On Wednesday night, Pennington, 25, of Harlan County, was crushed to death in a
  3938. rock fall at a Bell County Coal Corp. mine — one of two underground mining deaths
  3939. hours apart in Eastern Kentucky.
  3940. Eric Chaney, 26, of Pike County, was crushed in a roof collapse early yesterday at a
  3941. Dags Branch Coal Corp. mine in Fedscreek in Pike County, officials said.
  3942. The deaths were the second and third fatal mining accidents in Kentucky this year,
  3943. and the first underground fatalities. Nationally, 14 miners have died in accidents this
  3944. year.
  3945. ***
  3946. Bill Caylor, president of the Kentucky Coal Association, an industry group, said the
  3947. two deaths were unavoidable accidents. "We don't want things like this to happen, but
  3948. they will," Caylor said. "Mining is very safe, but you have to be careful because you're
  3949. working around big pieces of equipment."
  3950. Or maybe Kevin Lupardus died because he made a bad decision:
  3951. Investigation of fatal accident at Boone mine continues
  3952. CHARLESTON, W.Va.- State and federal authorities are trying to determine what
  3953. caused a section of high wall to fall onto an excavator at a Boone County surface mine,
  3954. killing the machine's operator. The accident occurred at about 2 a.m. Saturday November
  3955. 21, at Independence Coal's Red Cedar Surface Mine near Clothier. Independence Coal, a
  3956. subsidiary of Richmond, Va.-based Massey Energy, operates the mine as Endurance
  3957. Mining, according to federal Mine Safety and Health Administration records. Kevin Lee
  3958. Lupardus, 41, of Mabscott, was operating the excavator when a "large section" of the
  3959. highwall fell onto the machine's cab, said Terry Farley, an administrator with the state
  3960. Office of Miners' Health Safety and Training.
  3961. It is somewhat ironic that this program is starting now. Clearly acting Assistant
  3962. Secretary Dye hasn't read the June 2005 issue of Occupational Health & Safety which
  3963. contains an article by Fred Manuele entitled "Serious Injury Prevention."
  3964. Manuele cites experts who point out that what may look like "human error" are
  3965. actually system errors:
  3966. R. B. Whittingham, in his book The Blame Machine: Why Human Error Causes
  3967. Accidents, describes how disasters and serious accidents result from recurring, but
  3968. potentially avoidable, human errors. He shows that such errors are preventable because
  3969. they result from defective systems within a company.
  3970. Whittingham identifies the common causes of human error and the typical system
  3971. deficiencies that lead to those errors. They are principally organizational, cultural, and
  3972. management system deficiencies. Whittingham says that in some organizations, a "blame
  3973. culture" exists whereby the focus in incident investigation is on individual human error,
  3974. and the corrective action is limited to that level. He writes: "Organizations, and
  3975. sometimes whole industries, become unwilling to look too closely at the system faults
  3976. which caused the error"
  3977. He notes that although humans may be involved in the errors that lead to accidents,
  3978. James Reason and Alan Hobbs, in Managing Maintenance Error: A Practical Guide
  3979. point out that one needs to look deeper:
  3980. Errors are consequences not just causes. They are shaped by local circumstances: by
  3981. the task, the tools and equipment and the workplace in general. If we are to understand
  3982. the significance of these factors, we have to stand back from what went on in the error
  3983. maker's head and consider the nature of the system as a whole . . . this book has a
  3984. constant theme . . . that situations and systems are easier to change than the human
  3985. condition
  3986. In other words, look at the safety systems and find the root causes. If managers (and
  3987. MSHA)continue to attempt to prevent accidents by focusing on human errors and "wrong
  3988. decisions," the same accidents, injuries and deaths will continue to happen.
  3989. 4. Labor Relations in the Health Care Industry for Nurses224
  3990. More Nurses Needed
  3991. * Understaffing: There are not enough nurses to do what needs to be done on any
  3992. given shift and the nurses who are on duty are exhausted and stressed. A 2003 study by
  3993. the Institute of Medicine (IOM) found the environment in which nurses work a breeding
  3994. ground for medical errors which will continue to threaten patient safety until
  3995. substantially reformed. The IOM points to numerous studies showing that increased
  3996. infections, bleeding and cardiac and respiratory failure are associated with inadequate
  3997. numbers of nurses. A 2002 report by the Joint Commission on Accreditation of
  3998. Healthcare Organizations called the nursing shortage “a prescription for danger” and
  3999. found that a shortage of nurses contributed to nearly a quarter of the anticipated
  4000. problems that result in death or injury to hospital patients.
  4001. * Low Nurse-to-Patient Ratios: With managed care restructuring the health care
  4002. industry in the 1990s, hospitals reduced staffing levels to lower costs. Nurses care for
  4003. more patients and patients who are more acutely ill due to shorter hospital stays. One
  4004. study of hospital staffing found that decreases in the number of LPN/LVNs added to
  4005. RNs’ patient load. Studies have linked low nurse-to-patient ratios to medical errors and
  4006. to poorer patient outcomes, as well as to nurses leaving patient care. A 2002 study by
  4007. Linda Aiken, et al., found that for each additional patient over four in an RN’s workload,
  4008. the risk of death increases by 7% for hospital patients. Patients in hospitals with eight
  4009. patients per nurse have a 31% higher risk of dying than those in hospitals with four
  4010. patients per nurse. The IOM study recommends that nurse staffing levels be raised in all
  4011. health care facilities.
  4012. * Mandatory Overtime and Floating: Because of the nursing shortage, many
  4013. hospitals routinely require nurses to work unplanned or mandatory overtime and to
  4014. “float” to departments outside their expertise. On average, RNs work 8.5 weeks of
  4015. overtime per year according to a recent union survey. Mandatory overtime was an issue
  4016. in several recent strikes and 77% of RNs favor a law banning it except when an
  4017. emergency is declared.
  4018. * Burnout: Among nurses there are high rates of emotional exhaustion and job
  4019. dissatisfaction which are strongly associated with inadequate staffing and low nurse-topatient ratios. The Aiken study found each additional patient per nurse corresponds to a
  4020. 23% increased risk of burnout, as well as a 15% increase in the risk of job
  4021. dissatisfaction.
  4022. What's even worse, management's penny-wise, pound-foolish policies, which attempt
  4023. to cut costs by deliberate understaffing, don't really even save money:
  4024. Statistical model shows [sic] that when nursing units are understaffed the additional
  4025. 224
  4026. Michigan State University, School of Labor and Industrial Relations, "Labor Relations in the Health
  4027. Care Industry for Nurses: Online Credit Program"
  4028. <http://www.lir.msu.edu/distance_learning/MNAArticleandWebPage.htm>.
  4029. costs associated with patients who develop complications are greater than the labor
  4030. savings due to understaffing....
  4031. While immediate personnel costs are less with short staffing, long term costs were
  4032. higher because patients with complications often stay longer in the hospital and require
  4033. other expensive treatments....
  4034. Institutions attempting to decrease costs through health care worker reductions may,
  4035. in the final analysis, incur higher costs as a result of higher rates of nosocomial infection,
  4036. longer hospital stays and use of expensive antimicrobials and increased mortality.225
  4037. It's just another example of the MBA disease: stripping organizations of productive
  4038. assets and milking them in order to inflate short-term returns.
  4039. By the way: the healthcare industry has its very own "behavioral safety" approach to
  4040. hospital-acquired infections, directly analogous to the "human error" approach described
  4041. above in the mining industry. The spread of MRSA and other infections in hospitals is the
  4042. direct result of downsizing and understaffing--also the primary cause of patient falls,
  4043. medication errors, wrong site surgery, etc., etc., etc., etc., ad nauseam. Healthcare workers
  4044. know they need to wash their hands--but knowing and being able to do are two different
  4045. things when the only orderly on the floor is literally running from one call light to
  4046. another, and he's got three patients sitting on bedside commodes at the same time as two
  4047. other fall-risk patients are setting off their bed alarms. Rather than deal with the root
  4048. cause--the dangerous levels of understaffing that have resulted from the downsizings of
  4049. the past decade--hospital administrators resort to asinine gimmicks like the "Partners in
  4050. Your Care" program (designed by a manufacturer of hand disinfectants):
  4051. Patients and families are asked to be Partners in Your Care by asking all healthcare
  4052. workers that have direct contact with their family member patient “Did You Wash Your
  4053. Hands?” or “Did You Sanitize Your Hands?”226
  4054. Dilbert effectively parodied a similar program: the company response to on-thejob accidents was a "safety dog" who admonished "Woof, woof! Don't use scissors!"
  4055. Attempts to deal with safety issues through such behavioral approaches, rather
  4056. than by addressing the structural and process causes, are what Peter Drucker called
  4057. "management by drives" and Deming dismissed as "slogans, exhortations, and revival
  4058. meetings." But in the modern workplace, such slogans and gimmicks are likely to
  4059. appear on the very same bulletin board as kwality jargon from Six Sigma or ISO9000.
  4060. 225
  4061. Wisconsin Federation of Nurses and Health Professionals, "A Summary of Recent Research
  4062. Supporting the Need for Staffing Ratios and Workload Limitations in Healthcare"
  4063. <http://www.wfnhp.org/setlimits/researchsummary.html> Link no longer active, but available through
  4064. Internet Archive.
  4065. 226
  4066. Official Steris corporate website. http://www.steris.com/aic/partners.cfm
  4067. Appendix 8B
  4068. Corporate Rhetoric vs. Corporate Reality: The Case of
  4069. "Chainsaw Al" Dunlap
  4070. In a 1995 Wall Street Journal article by Alex Markels and Joann S. Lublin,227 I saw
  4071. one Albert J. Dunlap, referred to as simply a "turnaround specialist" and CEO of Scott
  4072. Paper, quoted on the wisdom of eliminating employee longevity awards.
  4073. To some managers, rewarding long service reinforces the very attitude of entitlement they
  4074. are trying to stamp out.
  4075. Last year, Scott Paper dropped its entire service-award program as part of a broad
  4076. restructuring. "We [were] rewarding longevity and the status quo; the status quo had been an
  4077. abysmal failure," says Albert J. Dunlap, a turnaround specialist hired as chairman and chief
  4078. executive last year to revive Scott’s sagging fortunes. Mr. Dunlap concedes that he "got some
  4079. grief" over the move, but he wasn’t swayed.
  4080. Like other companies cutting awards, Scott also cited a desire to cut costs. "Everybody
  4081. likes to go to big dinners and get nice awards," Mr. Dunlap says. "But it’s not right. You’re
  4082. using shareholders’ money," he adds.
  4083. When I read that quote, my only immediate reaction was to wonder just how
  4084. enormous an executive compensation package Mr. Dunlap received, whether he felt
  4085. "entitled" to it, and whether he thought it came from shareholders' money. But the name
  4086. seemed to ring a bell, for some reason. Having read Arianna Huffington's Pigs at the
  4087. Trough a few weeks earlier, I checked to see if I might have seen Dunlap mentioned in
  4088. there. And boy, howdy, was he!228 Contrasting his pious rhetoric above to his swinish
  4089. behavior is a lesson in hypocrisy.
  4090. I mentioned Dunlap, in Chapter Seven, as evidence that Mises' much-vaunted doubleentry bookkeeping, which he promoted as a panacea for the agency problems resulting
  4091. from the separation of ownership from control, is of little avail when the agent is keeping
  4092. the books. Dunlap was a master of the game when it came to massaging the numbers,
  4093. gaming the short-term profits and maximize his stock options and bonuses, taking off
  4094. with the loot, and leaving a gutted shell behind.
  4095. 227
  4096. Alex Markels and Joann S. Lublin, "Management: Longevity-Reward Programs Get Short Shrift," The
  4097. Wall Street Journal, April 27, 1995 <http://www.markels.com/management.htm>.
  4098. 228
  4099. Arianna Huffington, Pigs at the Trough: How Corporate Greed and Political Corruption are
  4100. Undermining America (New York: Crown Publishers, 2003), pp. 62-65.
  4101. Dunlap didn't just massage the numbers. He gave them a thorough rolfing. And the
  4102. scale of downsizing he practiced, which earned him the nickname "Chainsaw Al," make
  4103. Bob Nardelli look positively prodigal.
  4104. His final downfall resulted from his performance at Sunbeam, a Boca Raton appliance
  4105. maker. His approach to "turning around" that underperforming company was to fire half
  4106. the workforce, close 18 of 26 plants, and eliminate 80% of the product line. That, in
  4107. itself, wouldn't be so remarkable. That's just an extreme version of the typical MBA
  4108. playbook these days.
  4109. What's really remarkable is the appalling lengths he went to, in using accounting
  4110. jugglery to deceive shareholders. His gutting of productive capability didn't make the
  4111. company profitable, or increase the value of the shares. So, as Huffington said, "[i]f he
  4112. couldn't actually make the company profitable, Dunlap decided, he could at least make it
  4113. look profitable on paper."
  4114. With a little help from the corporate criminal's best friend, the master chefs of bookcooking at Arthur Andersen, Dunlap used illegal accounting tricks to shift revenue around,
  4115. which had the effect of increasing Sunbeam's reported losses under previous management.
  4116. Millions of dollars of expenses incurred in 1997, his first full year at Sunbeam, were charged
  4117. to 1996 instead. Dunlap then dipped into the artificial reserve to inflate accounts and
  4118. "increase" earnings. Here's how an SEC spokesman later described Dunlap's scam: "You
  4119. load up the cookie jar with improper reserves and then when you need a sugar jolt, which in
  4120. this example is positive earnings, you reach into the cookie jar."
  4121. We've already seen, in Chapter Seven, Martin Hellwig's reference to the standard
  4122. corporate practice of accumulating large reserves of real estate and other investments, in
  4123. order to smooth out cash flow in bad years.
  4124. It's especially comical to read the WSJ's reference to Dunlap above as exemplifying
  4125. opposition to ordinary production workers' "attitude of entitlement," and his pious words
  4126. about "the shareholders' money," in light of his performance at Sunbeam. The extent of
  4127. his respect for "the shareholders' money" should be pretty clear from the account above.
  4128. As for "attitudes of entitlement," how's this: When called to account before the
  4129. Sunbeam board of directors, he went shouted, "I'm much too rich and much too powerful
  4130. to have to take this shit from you!"